The SA bond market does not make a lot of sense. For borrowers, especially the RSA, to ignore the long end of the bond market would.

14th July 2020

The SA bond market reacted sharply to the spread of Covid19 and the ever more likely prospect of a damaging economic lock-down. Long term interest rates were pushed higher earlier in 2020 in response to SA’s deteriorating fiscal trends even before the full damage to be caused by lock-downs to the economy and the budget deficits were recognized.  Long rates then reversed as the crisis in financial markets passed by with lots of aid form central banks in the developed world. However the gap between long and short yields in SA had widened sharply and remained very wide, despite the bond market recovery, as the Reserve Bank cut its repo rate.

 

Fig. 1; RSA long and short rates Daily Data 2015-2020- July 10th

f1

Source; Bloomberg, Iress, Investec Wealth and Investment

 

The RSA ten-year bond currently (July 10th) yields 9.67% p.a. while the yield on a three month Treasury Bill is 3.96% p.a. a positive spread of 5.67% p.a. This means that the slope of the yield curve is far steeper than at any time over the past 15 years. close to 10% p.a. Another way of putting this is that the SA taxpayer has to pay an extra 5.67% p.a. to borrow long rather than short.

 

Fig.2: The slope of the RSA yield curve; 10 year – 3 month yields. Daily Data 2020 to July 10th  

f2

Source; Bloomberg, Iress, Investec Wealth and Investment

 

On the face of it this would appear to be a very expensive exercise for the SA government to borrow for a longer-term rather than to roll over short term debt. Given the current strains on tax revenues and the rapidly widening fiscal deficit and the government borrowing requirements is it a choice the Treasury is likely to exercise? Or is it going to finance a much greater proportion of its growing debt at the cheaper short term end of the term structure of interest rates? We think the answer will be and should be yeas to this question. We will attempt to provide more insight as to the borrowing choices the SA Treasury is likely to exercise over the coming months and years.

The answer is perhaps less obvious than it appears at first glance. The expectations theory of interest rates would posit, with very good reason, that the long-term rate is but the average of the expected short term rates over the period of any loan. Hence in principle there would be no good reason to prefer long over short-term lending or borrowing. Borrowing long or short and having to roll over shorter term debts should be expected to turn out about the same for borrowers or lenders with choices.

However, if interest rates at the short end rise faster than expected, borrowing long (and lending short) would turn out to be the better option. And vice versa if interest rates were to rise less than expected borrowing short and then rolling over short term debt would have been the better option. As would lending long.

The chances of unexpected fast or slow increases in short rates over the relevant period must be about the same- if the market behaves consistently with the consensus of expectations. Choosing to borrow short or long or lending long or short, given the freedom to choose either option, then represents speculation, the belief that the borrower or lender can beat the market, a belief that may turn out right or wrong- with the same probabilities- given the rationality of the expectations of interest rates.

This notion of equilibrium in the capital market surely makes sense, lenders and borrowers with the option to lend or borrow for shorter or longer periods would presumably expect to pay out the same or earn the same, one way or the other. If you could lend or borrow for three months at a time or for six months at an agreed rate today the expected interest, to be received or paid out over two consecutive three-month periods must presumably be the same as the interest rate fixed for six months. Thus the average (compounding) interest received or paid if the contract was fixed for three months at a known rate and then re-negotiated after three months at a rate, only to be known in three months time, must be expected to be the same. If the current three- month rate is below the six-month rate then it follows that the three months rate in three-months must be expected to rise to make the expected returns on the interest paid or received equivalent.

If this is not the case there would be every incentive to borrow or lend for longer or shorter periods depending on which was expected to suit better. It is the attempts to minimize or maximise interest paid or received that eliminates any such obvious market beating opportunities.

Thus according to the theory, if the three-month rate is below the six-month rate, then the three- month rate must be expected to rise above the current fixed six month rate in order to average out at the higher rate. Thus a positively sloped yield curve, long rates above short, implies that short rates are expected to rise above the current longer term rate over the duration of the lending and borrowing contract. And vice-versa if the yield curve is sloping downwards, short rates must be expected to fall below the alternative longer fixed-term rate. The same logic applies to longer term contracts. If the ten year RSA bond yield is above the yield on a five year bond, the five year bond yields will be expected to rise over the ten year period enough to provide the same expected, compounding, average return.

The RSA yield curve has had a consistently positive slope since 2005 with the exception of the boom period of 2006-2008 when short rates rose sharply and the rapid growth in the economy was clearly expected to slow down and bring lower short rates with it. As transpired with the aid of the Global Financial Crisis and the recession in SA that followed. As may be seen in the figure below the slope of the RSA yield curve has been at its most positive in 2020. It would therefore for almost all of this period been helpful to have borrowed short rather than long.

Fig.3; Long and Short Term interest rates in SA and the Slope of the Yield curve. Daily Data 2005- July 10th 2020.

f3

Source; Bloomberg, Iress, Investec Wealth and Investment

 

The slope of the term structure of interest rates, the differences between longer and shorter yields, allows us to interpolate the shorter-term interest rates expected in-between. Thus for a portfolio manager at a SA insurance company to prefer the 3.44% p.a. received currently for a 12 month RSA Treasury Note Bill rather than the 7.07% on offer for a RSA bond fixed for five years, or the fixed 10.05 % p.a. available from a ten year RSA bond, must mean that the one year yield is expected to rise sharply over the next five or ten years. That is to make lending short rather than long the sensible choice to make.

To provide equivalent returns lending long or short and rolling over each year the one year rate (now 3.4%) would have to more than doubled to 7.31%  in two years. Then increased further to 8.91% after three years and then on to to 11.5%  after five years. After ten years the one-year rate would need to be as much as 14.75% to make preferring one-year loans to five or ten year ones the sensible decision. (See figure below)

 

 

Fig.4; RSA one year (forward rates) implicit in the current slope of the yield (for on to ten years)

f4

Source; Thompson-Reuters, Investec Wealth and Investment

 

It is very difficult to reconcile such expectations with the likely reactions of the Reserve Bank over the next few crucial years. The outlook for GDP growth is very grim and the expectations for inflation over the next few years remain highly subdued. The compensation for taking on inflation risk in the RSA bond market is currently only an extra 3.9% p.a. to be earned over five years. That is 3.9% is the extra yield available from a nominal 5 year bond over its inflation protected alternative.

 

Fig.5; RSA nominal and real 5 year bond yields and their spread- inflation compensation for five years.

f5

 

Source; Bloomberg,  Investec Wealth and Investment

 

Therefore if we subtract this estimate of average inflation expected over the next five years implied in the bond market, from the one year interest rate expected in five-year’s time, we get an after inflation expected return that year 5 of about 6%. This measure of inflation expected is now very close to actual inflation. As are the inflation expectations surveyed and reported by the Reserve Bank and forecast by them. They will all have declined further since the beginning of the year given the global pressures on inflation and the likely reluctance of SA households and firms to spend more over the next few years.

It is very difficult to imagine that the SA economy will be strong enough, or the Reserve Bank aggressive enough, over the next few years, to tolerate real interest rates of the order implied by the yield curve and the spread between nominal and real yields now available in the bond market. Therefore many borrowers, especially the SA government, is surely likely to take the risk that short term interest will not rise nearly as rapidly as implied by the current slope of the yield curve. After all short-term rates are directly controlled by the Reserve Bank itself.

Borrowing long can be avoided and the growing SA government debt can much better be funded short rather than long, and by rolling over short term debt for as long, provided the level of long-term rates remains where they are. Drawing further on the government deposits at the Reserve Bank is a further low interest cost option. The Reserve Bank can also provide the banks with enough extra cash, on favourable enough terms, to have them support the growing market in short-term debt. Any reduced supply of longer-term paper will help take pressure off longer term yields.

For the government to elect to borrow long rather than short in current circumstances would surely now seem the wrong, very expensive option. The current state of the bond market could be argued to be something of an aberration in a world of global bond markets that have been monetized to an extraordinary degree. In the longer run the task for the SA government is to prove to the world that it can manage its debt in a sensible way. This means convincing potential lenders that it can bring government spending closely in line with its ability to raise tax revenues. This will help to bring down the long-term cost of raising RSA debt. In the short term, until the crisis is over, and the economy normalizes, what is called for from the government and its Reserve Bank, is the ability to manage the unavoidably larger national debt and short-term interest rates in a sensible way. If we call it good debt management rather than money creation- that it will be to some degree- then so describe it that way

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Fear debt – not raising equity capital – when it makes economic sense.

The threat to the value of SA retailers as cash has drained away during the lock downs has been as damaging to their landlords. The value of the average market weighted general retailer and property company on the JSE is less than 40 % of what they were worth in January 2018. The damage to the balance sheets of the property company of Covid19 is perhaps far greater than that of the average retailer. Who have shown a greater willingness to raise fresh equity capital to repair their balance sheets

 

The Value of JSE listed Property Companies and General Retailers January 2018 =100 Month end data to June 2020.

f1

Source; Iress and Investec Wealth and Investment

 

A number of these  JSE listed Real Estate Investment Trusts (Reits) with seemingly little growth in expected to come from SA assets, sought faster growth offshore. These offshore investments were funded very largely sometimes exclusively with foreign currency denominated debt.

The market value of average JSE Reit assets less debts, their net asset value (NAV) had fallen away before the Covid crisis that then decimated their rental revenues at home and abroad. A number of these JSE listed Reits now lack a sufficient buffer of equity to absorb the losses from COVID 19 related shutdowns. Debt to market value ratios have risen and NAV fallen further.

To qualify as Reits and avoid corporate taxes they are required to pay out at least 75% of their income after interest and all other expenses. They are appealing for an exemption from the Treasury and the JSE to skip dividends to conserve cash and still retain their Reit status.

They might do much better to raise equity capital, if they can, issue more shares for cash and pay off foreign and domestic debts. Even if the saving on foreign interest paid is minimal, provided the rand holds up, the improvements to their survival prospects and so market value could be substantial. Shareholders supported by stronger balance sheets could be well served facing up to a reduction in cash distributions per share.  They would receive less income per share, but with lower risks attached to expectations of future distributions, this could add value to all the shares issued – even when there are more of them.

The purpose in raising capital may be, ideally, to grow a business successfully. Successful businesses mostly fund their growth from the cash they generate from operations. More unusually they may have to raise additional debt or equity capital secure the survival of a still potentially successful business.

The same fundamental question needs to be asked in both circumstances.  Will in other words the increase in the market value of the company, plus the dividends paid, both measured in extra rands come to exceed the amount of extra capital raised. also in rands. Plus something extra to cover the opportunity cost of the capita raised.   That is will the investment of extra capital return as much as could be expected from any alternative, as risky, a SA investment? Equal that is to the return from the bond market plus an equity risk premium- of about 5% p.a. (About 13% p.a.) If so investors will get all their capital back – and more – and perhaps very quickly as share prices could respond immediately to the expectation of good returns to come.

Any potential capital raise needed to save or de-risk a business will be reflected in the ongoing survival value of a company. Any surprising refusal of its owners to refuse to supply extra capital, when needed to secure the business as a going concern, will provide a very negative signal and surely damage the share price. Preventing the downside will be part of the upside of any capital raise.

A successful secondary issue, especially when underwritten by bankers exercising due diligence, is perhaps an even stronger signal of favourable longer- term prospects for any company. More so than a rights issue supported by established shareholders with everything to lose. With a successful secondary issue raising capital for the right value adding reasons, established shareholders can expect to have a smaller share of a larger cake and be better off for it.

The obvious way to maintain the share of established shareholders in a company is to raise extra debt, rather than equity capital. But more debt, makes any company more risky, and may destroy rather than add market value for shareholders. Debt only looks cheaper than equity with hindsight, after the good times have rolled by. And the good times may not last- as we have been so cruelly reminded.

A time to demand and supply extra capital for capital hungry business – post Covid19

A PS on the fundamentals of capital raising

The past quarter has been record breaking.  Records have been set in extra spending by governments measured as a share of (normal) GDP. For the developed world this additional emergency spending by governments has ranged between an extra 5 to as much as 15 per cent of GDP. Another record has been set in money created by central banks. Of the order of an extra 5 trillion dollars worth. Included in their current bout of QE have been substantial purchases of corporate debt.

The monetization of much debt has meant very low interest rates with which to fund rapidly growing fiscal deficits and rising debt to GDP ratios. Records are therefore also being set in the amount of cash raised by businesses. Since the end of March, U.S.-listed firms have raised a quarterly record beating $148 billion of extra capital. Monetary policy has made capital raising on a vast scale possible on increasingly favourable terms. And without which a strong recovery from the lockdowns would be impossible.

Loan guarantee schemes, provided to commercial banks by central banks backed up by their Treasuries, has been an important component of the financial relief promised. These loan guarantees – should they be fully required to offset defaults – which is not at all expected – are available on a very large scale. In normally fiscally conservative Germany extra government spending on relief is of the order of 15% of GDP while the loan guarantee provision is of the order of 30% of GDP. For the US the stimulus plan is equivalent to 7% of GDP with the guarantee adding another 8% of GDP to the package.

It makes every economic sense that ordinarily sound and profitable businesses in SA as elsewhere not be forced out of the economy for an inability to service or roll over their debts for reasons entirely beyond their control. And are able to start up again by recapitalising their operations – given how much capital has been lost during the lock downs

The South African economy has not benefitted from fiscal and monetary relief on anything like the scale offered elsewhere. The additional borrowing requirement of the SA government has surged to over 14% of GDP more than double the deficit planned in February as we learned from the Minister of Finance yesterday June 24th. Largely because largely because tax revenues have declined so sharply- by over R300b with further declines expected. Extra government spending on its adjusted Budget is estimated as but R36b.

Despite a relative lack of encouragement of the kind offered in the US and elsewhere to the market for corporate debt, the capital market in SA has been active. We have seen something of a flurry of capital raising by JSE listed companies. The issue of relevance to shareholders (and the banks underwriting the issues) is whether the extra capital intended to be raised can pay for itself. That is will the extra capital raised earn a return that will covers the (opportunity) cost of the capital raised. That is equivalent to the high long-term RSA bond yield of 8% plus a equity risk premium of 4% or more for the least risky of businesses- something ahead of 12% p.a. returns for the least risky of enterprises.

If the answer is a positive one a rights issue or indeed any secondary issue to raise capital or indeed debts – should go ahead. And the hope must be that the market immediately shares this justifiable optimism and re-prices the company’s shares accordingly. That is prices the businesses raising additional capital them now for more likely survival rather than extinction.

The same positive answer is required of any business large or small that needs to raise capital to resume business post-Covid. Will the essential extra capital raised cover its risk-adjusted costs? We must hope that the SA financial markets, especially the banks, can help meet these additional, calls for extra capital. The loan guarantee scheme offered by the Reserve Bank in SA is perhaps the best hope for business and economic rescue.

The government has the task of ensuring that the capital market is up to this vital task of funding both government and business on sensible terms. Without which the prospects for a post-Covid recovery in SA, absent fiscal stimulation, remain especially bleak.  The burden of economic relief has passed to monetary policy.

Postscript on capital raising on the JSE

We have seen something of a flurry of intentions to raise additional capital raising by JSE listed companies.  The latest by retailers the Foschini Group (TFG) and Pepkor in the form of rights issues to their shareholders. Mister Price (MPR) another retailer has also indicated an intention to raise more equity capital.

TFG announced plans on June 18th 2020 to raise R3.95b from its shareholders, equivalent to 22% of its current market value of approximately R17.5b. A market value that has shrunk by more than half this year on fears of exposure to Covid19 accompanied by  a seemingly debt laden balance sheet. The market has however reacted somewhat favourably to the announcement. The share price has held up since the announcement and regained a little lost ground when compared to the Truworths (TRU) share price, a rival retailer. ( See below the figures that chart the market value of TFG over recent years and where we compare the TFG share price to that of clothing retail rival Truworths (TRU)

 

TFG Market Value of Company Daily Data; 2016- June 22nd 2020

f1

Source; Iress and  Investec Wealth and Investment

 

 

TFG Share price and Ratio of TFG to TRU share prices – Daily Data 2020 to June 24th

f2

Source; Iress and Investec Wealth and Investment

 

The terms of the TFG rights issue (to be underwritten by a consortium of banks) will only be announced should the proposal gain shareholder approval on the 16th July. It should be understood that as a rights issue this extra capital cannot reduce the share of the established shareholders in the company, should they follow their rights. They may however prefer to sell such rights to subscribe extra capital. This benefit in selling the rights to subscribe can be regarded as compensation for giving up a share of the company’s profits and dividends and market value in the future.

The value of their rights will depend on the difference between the subscription price and the ruling market price. The larger this discount, the more shares will have to be issued to raise the required 3.95b – but only from its own shareholders. Hence there need be no dilution of shareholders. The market value of TFG must have increased by at least R3.95b for the shareholders to break even on their additional investment. They will be hoping for more upside over time. And some of the upside may even have been registered already in anticipation of the rights issue going through, even before the announcement of the rights issue itself, because of the better times it portends for the company.

The larger the difference between the ruling market price and the price at which the additional shares will be offered (the larger the discount) the more likely the rights will have value and be taken up. This outcome is only of importance to the underwriters. The more enthusiastic the response, the fewer shares the banks will have to take up. Presumably in this case the intention of the underwriters is not to hold shares in TFG.

A rights issue is equivalent to an additional investment by a sole shareholder in a company. The nominal value attached to the additional shares will be of no consequence other than to determine the number of extra shares issued, as identified in the books- all with the same owner. In practice the additional capital invested in a non-listed business  is very likely to be identified as loan rather than share capital, to enable the owner to rank equally with other creditors in the event of a business failure

The issue of relevance to shareholders is will the extra R3.95b. of capital raised will pay for itself over time. That is earn a return over time on the R3.95b of additional capital that more than covers the cost of the capital raised. To add value for shareholders such future returns would need to average around 12-13 per cent per annum.  That is to presume that the required returns from a retailer in SA would have to be at least equal to the returns certainly offered by a long dated government bond (currently about 9% p.a) plus a risk premium of 4% premium. They could hope to realise similar returns from any other JSE company taking similar risks with their capital.   If the answer is a positive one, that is to say expected returns promise economic profits or economic value added (EVA)  the rights issue or indeed any secondary issue (regardless of any dilution that might take place) should be approved.

There is a further consideration that established shareholders will bear in mind when approached for additional capital. The value of their shares will have declined in response to the damage caused to earnings and cash flow by the disruption of their ordinary activities caused by the lock down. Hence the need for additional capital. Companies that entered the lock down with relatively debt laden balance sheets will be recognised as more vulnerable to financial stress. However the prospect of a rights issue that would mitigate this danger would always be reflected, favourably, in the current value of the shares.

Any unexpected failure of shareholders to approve a share issue of this kind would surely raise the likelihood of default and immediately reduce the value of a shareholding. Not throwing good money after bad may be the right decision. But if it comes as a surprise to the market place such a refusal will provides a very negative signal. Vice versa if a surprising rights issue is successfully launched.

A successful secondary issue, underwritten by bankers, that does not demand participation by possibly jaundiced established shareholders, is perhaps an even stronger signal of favourable longer- term prospects for any company. The avoidance of dilution should not be a primary consideration in any capital raise. If the additional capital is expected to realise an economic profit, established shareholders will benefit in line with newly attracted shareholders. They can expect to have a smaller share of a larger cake and be better off for it.

The more obvious way to avoid dilution of established shareholders is to raise extra debt rather than equity capital. But the market for debt issues may not be as open as the equity market. As would appear to be the case in SA, but not in the USA. But more debt as we have seen makes any company r more risky. Andwhen business as usual is disrupted debt becomes particularly burdensome. Debt is not always cheaper than equity. It may appear so in the good times that may not last.

 

The same positive answer is required of any business large or small post Covid that needs to raise debt or equity capital to resume business post Covid. That is will it earn economic profits in the true opportunity cost sense? Will the investment beat its cost of capital, that is return more than is required to justify the investment?  We must hope that the SA financial markets, including most importantly the banks, can meet these additional, fully justifiable calls for extra capital. The government with its central bank has the task of ensuring that the capital market is up to this vital task.

The Reserve Bank should follow the lead of its developed market peers (and some emerging market peers) in its response to the Covid-19 crisis

It seems that investors in emerging markets hold their governments and central banks to a much higher fiscal and monetary standard than is expected of their increasingly indebted developed market peers.

What is deemed to be right for the increasingly indebted developed world hoping to recover from the coronavirus – that is massive doses of extra government spending and money creation in support of government debt – is treated with suspicion when proposed or attempted by increasingly indebted emerging market economies, including SA.

We have argued that economies such as our own, which have suffered even more damage from the lockdowns, thanks to more widespread poverty and in the absence of capital reserves accumulated by households and businesses, need all the unconventional help they can get.

Not all emerging market central banks have taken the chastity vow. In Indonesia, as the Financial Times (FT) reported on 15 June: “Finance Minister, Sri Mulyani Indrawati, says quantitative easing and other policies are restoring confidence. Indonesia is at the forefront of emerging markets in implementing monetary policy that was once seen as the preserve of developed economies.”

The minister said that “Indonesia will use unprecedented quantitative easing and other emergency monetary and fiscal policies for as long as it takes to recover from the coronavirus pandemic, according to the country’s finance minister.  With the private sector in retreat after weeks of lockdown, massive state spending was needed to shore up the economy”, adding that Indonesia would not rely on central bank financing in the long run: “That is not good policy practice.”

Brazil, according to the FT in another report (8 June) has granted its central bank extraordinary powers for the next 12 months, even though the Bank seems somewhat reluctant to employ them. Central bank President Roberto Campos Neto said he would not employ such measures until traditional tools had been exhausted:

“We still think we have monetary space on the traditional policy. If you start using unconventional policy before you exhaust the conventional policy, you create noise that makes the central bank lose credibility.”
However, according to the FT, the central bank has slashed Brazil’s benchmark Selic interest rate to a historic low of 3% and is expected to cut by a further 75 basis points this month. Campos Neto said there was now greater clarity on the extent of the damage likely to be wrought by the coronavirus pandemic and that “uncertainty regarding the extreme cases has diminished”. The Bank in March launched a US$300bn financial liquidity package — equivalent to 16.7% of the country’s GDP — to mitigate the efforts of the broad economic shutdown caused by the coronavirus pandemic. “I don’t think any other country has done anything close to that,” Campos Neto said.

The case for extraordinary policies is clear enough. When economies are allowed to normalise, hopefully extra demand will match extra potential supplies that then become available. Extra spending to accompany extra output can be assisted by extra government spending – on income relief and relief for lenders and borrowers. Money creation by central banks can make it cheaper to issue more government debt and to encourage banks to lend more freely. In the absence of stimulus, the willingness of firms to increase output and to offer employment on normal terms would be more compromised. They are unlikely to hold optimistic forecasts of revenues and profits upon which to budget. The case for stimulus is thus every bit as strong in the less developed world, including SA.

There is as yet no indication that the SA Reserve Bank sees the crisis as calling for anything like such a vigorous a response. It remains largely in conventional inflation-targeting mode. The supply of central bank money, notes in circulation together with the cash deposits of the banks with the Reserve Bank, defined as the money base or M0, sometimes more evocatively described as high powered money, did not increase at all since the end of last year to May 2020.

Money base to May 2020

f1

Source: SA Reserve Bank Balance Sheets and Data Bank, and Investec Wealth & Investment

This unchanged level of the money base through the crisis occurred despite the purchase by the Reserve Bank of a modest extra R22bn of RSA bonds in the secondary market (modest by comparison with the other assets held by the Bank that are dominated by its foreign exchange reserves). In May 2020, as a result of drawing on its large deposits with the Bank to make payments abroad, the foreign assets of the Bank declined. Despite the limited QE designed to smooth volatility in the debt markets rather than to stimulate, and despite a significant increase in Reserve Bank loans to banks, net-net the money base has not increased during this time of grave crisis. We show the trends in the assets of the Reserve Bank and its liability to the government in the chart below.

Government deposits are not part of the money base held by the public and the banks. An increase in government deposits reduces the money base and a decline will do the opposite, provided the drawdown is used to fund spending or debt repayments in SA. If, as appears to have been the case in May 2020, the payments by the government (drawing down its deposits) went to foreign creditors and so foreign banks, the SA banks will thus not have seen an increase in their cash reserves and deposits with the Reserve Bank. In May, the loans to private banks declined sharply – also reducing the money base. Thus, despite the purchase of an additional R10bn of government stock by the Reserve Bank, the money base in May was practically unchanged and no larger than it was in December.

In the charts below, we show the Reserve Bank balance sheet over the period since December  and the monthly changes in some of the key items that move the money base – the notes in circulation plus the deposits of the banks with the Reserve Bank.

The money base in SA and its sources (December 2019 to May 2020)

f2
Source: SA Reserve Bank Balance Sheets and Data Bank, and Investec Wealth & Investment

Reserve Bank balance sheet – monthly movements affecting the money base (December 2019 to May 2020)

 f3
Source: SA Reserve Bank Balance Sheets and Data Bank, and Investec Wealth & Investment
SA desperately needs the same extraordinary interventions to counter the impact of the lockdown now underway in the developed world, and as we have indicated, also in some developing economies. Given the responses of the SA Treasury and Reserve Bank to date, it is not surprising that the consensus forecasts of market analysts are for a below average reduction in SA GDP in 2020 of 6%, but thereafter for a well below increase in GDP in 2021, a pedestrian 2%.

What is called for is firstly a properly vigorous response to the crisis. It also calls for a credible commitment to a return to fiscal and monetary normality when the crisis is over, and when the economy is operating at something like its potential. That long-term growth potential surely has to be above 2% annual growth. To realise permanently faster growth, needs more than effective crisis management. It calls for reforms of the economy.

The rand and growing the SA economy. How not to waste the crisis.

 

Post the lock downs the patterns of household spending are widely expected to change permanently. How it will change is of overwhelming importance to almost all business that supply households or are once or twice or three times removed from making sales directly to households. The demand to fly to some holiday destination not only affects hotels, B&B’s, restaurants, airports, travel agents, airlines and car rental companies taxi companies and all they employ or contract with – it will have the most profound implications for Boeing and Airbus and all their component suppliers.

Household spending accounts for 60% of all spending in SA and 70% in the US and other developed economies. Absent the control and command of governments (very active in the lockdowns) the decisions of households to spend or save or borrow to spend always moves the economy in the one direction or another. The market-place, post-covid19, will make the same call on its suppliers to adapt profitably to changing tastes. And to innovate successfully. That is to lead household spending to their own portals, real or virtual, depending on what will work best and be rewarded accordingly.

There is every reason for governments and their central banks to ameliorate the economic damage of their own making and offer compensation for the loss of incomes from work- including for the owners of businesses. Governments have every reason to encourage the demand for all goods and services when they allow firms after the lockdown to do what comes so naturally to them. That is to freely compete for custom and for the resources, labour and capital and premises to help them do so. There is no more reason for governments to get involved trying to pick post-covid business winners or losers than they would have at any other time.

And to leave future taxpayers with as little a burden of interest to pay on the additional government debt that is being incurred. Printing money rather than issuing expensive debt (when debt is as expensive as it is for the SA taxpayer) makes very good sense. The inflation in SA that might ordinarily come with money creation is a long way away- that is until supply and demand, both so damaged by the crisis, can recover to something like their potential.

They say no crisis should be wasted. The crisis does provide an opportunity to stimulate what would be the most helpful source of growth for SA. That is export and import replacement led growth. The much weaker rand has made SA potentially much more competitive than it was only a few months ago. Adjusted for differences between SA and USA consumer price inflation the rand at USD/ZAR 17.50 is now about 50% undervalued Vs the dollar and about 18% more competitive with the US exporter or importer than it was at year end. A purchasing power equivalent dollar would now cost no more than R8.70 (See figure 1 below)

 

Fig.1; The USD/ZAR exchange rate and its Purchasing Power Equivalent[1] to May 27th 2020.

f1

Source; Bloomberg, Investec Wealth and Investment

There is a strong case for retaining this competitive advantage. It is very easy to inhibit exchange rate strength should it materialize. The Reserve Bank can buy dollars with the rands it has an unlimited supply of. The Swiss National Bank does this all the time to hold back the Swiss franc. Furthermore buying dollars with rands would add to the supply of rands – it would be another form of money creation. And very helpful when every extra rand may encourage more spending and lending – so urgently needed for the recovery.  Preventing exchange rate weakness should never be attempted.

In figure 2 below we chart the relationship between the purchasing power value of the rand and its market value. This relationship represents the real exchange value of the rand with lower values indicating real rand weakness, or equivalently greater competitiveness for SA producers, and vice versa. We compare the real rand dollar exchange rate using the Consumer Price Indexes for SA and the US and the real rand exchange rate as calculated by the Reserve Bank. This real exchange rate is adjusted for the prices of manufactured goods of our 20 largest trading partners (weighted by their importance in our trade) using the prices of manufactured goods as the basis of comparison. This ratio has not been updated since year end. Given the stronger dollar the depreciation of the real rand so calculated is generally less severe than the real dollar exchange rate. The nominal trade weighted rand has declined by 20% since year end and so the real rand is likely to have declined by a similar degree this year.

 

Fig2. The real rand Vs the US dollar and SA’s trading partners. (2010=100)

f2

Source; Bloomberg, SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth and Investment

 

The value of the real rand is totally dominated by changes in the market value of the rand that fluctuates so widely and unpredictably. We compare quarterly movements in the market trade weighted value of the rand and its inflation adjusted value. As may be seen it is very much a case of the market exchange rate leading and the direction of inflation following. Rather than inflation leading to compensating changes in the market value of the rand. The so called pass- through impact of a weaker or stronger rand on prices in SA depends also on the direction of import prices in USD.

Especially important for the price level in SA is the dollar piece of oil that makes up a large percentage of SA imports- up to 40% at times. With oil prices as low as they are now the pass-through effect on SA prices and inflation is likely to be very subdued. Exporters from SA especially of metals and minerals that still make up a large percentage of SA exports are largely price takers established in US dollars. The weaker rand translates automatically into higher rand prices and vice versa. How much the weaker rand drives up the costs of our exporters and those suppliers who compete with imports depends very much on the direction of SA inflation. This is likely to remain subdued for now given the general weakness of demand for goods, services and labour.

It is not only the level of the real rand that matters for the real economy. Movements in the market value of the rand and hence its real value of great importance for operating profit margins are also of great relevance. The USD/ZAR and the Euro/Rand exchange rate has been almost twice as variable on average as the USD/Euro exchange rate. This year is no exception. We show below how the volatility of these exchange rates on a daily basis this year.

Managing this volatility of the rand exchange rate is a burden carried by SA exporters and importers and those who compete with exports and imports.. It adds to their costs of hedging exchange rate risk and the pure uninsurable uncertainty about the actual direction of the rand demands a discouragingly higher expected return on their investments.

 

Fig.3 Quarterly per centage movements in the Nominal and Real Trade weighted rand – lower numbers indicate rand weakness.

f3

Source; Bloomberg, SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth and Investment

 

Fig.4; Volatility of the USD/ZAR, the USD/ZAR and the Euro/USD Daily Data 2020 to May 25th[2]

f4

Source; Bloomberg and Investec Wealth and Investment

 

There should be two objectives for exchange rate policy during and after the crisis. Firstly, should the opportunity present itself, to inhibit rand strength to encourage domestic production and consumption. Especially since inflation will be looking after itself well enough and interest rates do not need a stronger rand to decline further. The very weak domestic economy is reason alone for still lower interest rates.  Secondly, and a much more difficult longer-term exercise, would be to seek ways to inhibit exchange rate volatility that is such a burden on foreign trade.

 

[1] The PPP rand is calculated as USD/ZAR in December 2010 (USD/ZAR=6.31) multiplied by SA CPI/US CPI) 2010=100

 

[2] Volatility is calculated as the 30 day moving average of the Standard Deviation of daily percentage movements in the exchange rate

Is it time for money creation on a significant scale in SA?

Funding extra government spending via loans from the central bank, can be a helpful form of government finance when spending is growing rapidly to meet an emergency.

Today is a time of epidemiologists, central bankers and yes, of schemers too. We will discover in due course whose reputations will have survived the economic crisis better intact.1

Central banks have an essential duty to create extra money for a growing economy.  They do so on a consistent basis in normal times. Their extra money comes in two forms: as notes and coins and in the deposits private banks keep with their central banks.

The SA Reserve Bank has not failed in its duty to supply more cash to the economy over the past 20 years. For much of the period it might have supplied too much cash. More recently, it can be criticised for supplying too little for the health of the economy as we shall demonstrate.

The sum of the notes and the deposits issued by the SA Reserve Bank (the money base) grew by 7.9 times between 2000 and April 2020, from R35bn to R275bn at an average compound rate of 8.7% a year over 20 years.

Figure 1: SA Reserve Bank – Monthly supplies of notes and bank deposits

f1

Source: SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth & Investment

1 With apologies to Edmund Burke, responding to the excesses of the French Revolution: “Today is a time of sophists, economists and schemers.” – Reflections on the French Revolution

The ratio of the broadly defined money supply (M3), which includes bank deposits, to the money base (the money multiplier), reached a peak of nearly 17 before the financial crisis of 2008 and has now stabilised at about 14 times.

Figure 2: Calculating the money multiplier – the ratio of broad money (M3) to central bank money (money base) 2000 to 2019

f2Source: SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth & Investment

The Reserve Bank balance sheet has been updated to April 2020. The money base (notes plus bank deposits) as at the end of April 2020 was in fact R5bn smaller than it was at 2019 year-end, despite the crisis. The money base fell by R29.4bn between March and April 2020, even though the note issue itself rose by R4.82bn in April, surely in response to crisis fears. The deposits of the banks however fell more sharply, from R103.4bn in March to R77.34bn by April.

The Reserve Bank’s portfolio of government stock, a small part of its asset portfolio, grew from R8.1bn at year-end to R20.6bn in April.  This may be compared to loans made by the Reserve Bank for the banking system. They grew from R65.8bn at year-end to R103.9bn by March, but then (surprisingly in the crisis circumstances) fell back to R77.34bn by April month-end.

If the Reserve Bank were to embark on meaningful money supply growth loans to the banking system, its holdings of government stock would have to increase meaningfully. An increase in Reserve Bank lending to the banking system on favourable terms would allow the banks to support extra issues of short-term Teasury obligations at hopefully much lower rates of interest (see figures below for details of the balance sheets of SA banks since 2000 and of the Reserve Bank balance sheet this year).

Figure 3: SA banks deposit liabilities (M3), and uses and sources of cash

f3
Source: SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth & Investment

Figure 4: The Reserve Bank balance sheet (selected items) to April 2020

f4
Source: SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth & Investment

There is always a temptation for a government to borrow money from its central bank to fund its expenditure by issuing money. Almost zero cost money may be issued as an alternative to raising taxes or paying interest on the debt it raises to fund its expenditure. It is a temptation that is widely (but not always) resisted.

How much money should be created as a service to an economy and its banks that manage the payments system? The answer in very general terms is for a central bank to supply not too much and not too little cash for the economy. Not too much – that is not to supply more than the households, businesses and banks would willingly hold as a reserve of spending power. But to supply enough extra cash to satisfy demands that would grow normally in line with real economic activity.

It is not the supply of money and of associated bank and other credit that represents inflationary dangers or the danger of asset price bubbles that must all end badly for an economy. It is the excess of the supply of money – over the willingness to hold the extra money supplied – that is to be avoided if inflation is to be controlled.

Also to be avoided is to supply too little money. If the supply of extra money is constrained, economic actors would be inclined to cash in assets or save more to build up a cash reserve. This too would not be good for an economy.

The task central banks set themselves is to smooth the business, money and credit cycles by adjusting the cost of the money they supply to the economic system. They raise the repo or discount rates they charge the banks who borrow from them, when the economy and the supply of bank credit appears to be accelerating too rapidly. They will also lower the cost of their money, reduce the repo or discount rates, to encourage the banks to extend more credit to avoid or overcome a recession. However this fine balance of additional supplies of and demands for money is seldom achieved. The business cycle has not been eliminated by modern monetary policy.

The business cycle – extended periods of above and then below potential real growth – can be mostly linked to phases of more rapid and then much slower growth in money supply and bank credit. Inflation, for which a central bank usually has a target range, will tend to follow the direction of the business cycle.

The times when the price level takes a course independently of the direction of the business cycle calls for particularly sensitive attention by the monetary authorities. Raising interest rates in response to a supply side shock to the economy that results in temporarily higher prices (for example following a shock to the oil price, food supplies or to the exchange rate) may well prove to be pro- rather than counter-cyclical. It may slow the economy down further than it might otherwise have done.

These norms and objectives for monetary policy do not apply in the extremes of a crisis, when sudden demands for extra cash threaten the banking financial and payments system. The solution for a crisis is for a central bank to supply as much extra cash as is necessary to prevent ordinarily sound businesses and financial institutions from going under and dragging the economy down with them.

Shutting down an economy to fight a pandemic is a new challenge for monetary policy. It also calls for a rapid increase in the supply of central bank money and sharply lower interest rates where there is room to lower them.

Funding extra government spending via loans from the central bank, or funded by a banking system well supported with loans from the central bank, is a helpful form of government finance when spending is  growing rapidly to meet an emergency, and correctly so. Funding with money or near money avoids the long-term burden for taxpayers of funding extra debt issues at high interest rates in an unwilling capital market. And by adding extra money to the system, it makes a much-needed recovery of spending more likely when the economy comes out of lockdown.

The extra money cannot be inflationary until the economy and spending recovers. At that point, the growth in the supply of money and credit can be reduced or reversed in the usual way.

When an economy is forced to its knees, an emphasis on inflation targets makes little sense. SA urgently needs and deserves (proportionately) as much extra money as is being provided in the developed world. By contrast, the money base in the US has been increased by 40% this year with more money on the way.

South Africa should not be held to a different fiscal or monetary policy standard in a time of crisis.

The history of the Corona virus catastrophe will come to be written. The costs as well as the benefits of lock downs will be calculated as best they can. The benefits and costs of not locking down as in Sweden or Brazil, will provide useful comparisons.

The benefits will be measured in infections avoided and in lives saved. The future incomes of those spared to continue productive working lives will be measured as part of the economic benefits realised. As should all the collateral damage from other medical threats to survival not adequately dealt with because of the attention focused so heavily on the victims of Corona virus. On the positive side of the cost benefit equation, damage avoided from fewer fatalities and injuries on the roads or in the factories and mines will be part of the calculation. The costs of the lock down will be calculated, much less controversially as the value of incomes and output sacrificed in the lock downs.

The history lessons learnt may teach us about how best to cope with a future pandemic of inevitably uncertain cause, effects and consequences. And where the appropriate policy responses can never be obvious before the spread of the disease. The relationship between the economic costs and medical benefits of any policy responses to an epidemic deserve the most careful consideration. We are not at all sure they have been properly calibrated.

The case for governments building a large and yet very expensive reserve of medical capacity will have been greatly strengthened by what has happened. If only to allow for more time for leaders and their advisors to assess any new unknown pandemic threat to the community. A reserve that would allow more time for science to come to the rescue, before hospital facilities are overwhelmed, and so perhaps avoid the highly expensive lock downs.

What the lock downs will have cost their economies before economic life returns to something like normal will be measured with some degree of accuracy after the event. It will be the difference between all that might have been produced or earned (that is measured by gross domestic product (GDP) had economies not been shut down to a lesser or greater degree, and what has been produced and earned despite the lock downs.

It is possible to forecast potential GDP by extrapolating the underlying trend in outputs and incomes before the crisis. A more complicated econometric model could attempt the same forecasts. The difference between this potential GDP and the GDP delivered over the two or three years, post the crisis, will give us an accurate enough estimate of the costs of the lock down.

We have estimated a GDP loss ratio for SA under lock down. We have made a broad-brush estimate of how much of potential GDP will be produced each quarter in SA. It is assumed in Q1 2020 that SA GDP will run at 90% of its potential, then in Q2, when the knock down impact will be at its most severe, we judge that the GDP will then run at 75% of what have been delivered without the crisis. Thereafter each quarter, the loss of output ratio reduces by 5% per quarter. That is GDP will rise to 80% of potential GDP to be produced in Q3, 90% in Q4, 95% in Q1 2021 and then back to 100% in Q2 2021.

This would mean a V shaped recovery bringing the economy back to its potential by mid-2021. This might be an optimistic scenario. But even so the loss in GDP each quarter on these assumptions could amount to a large over R1 trillion by Q2 2021.  Whatever the more precise measure of actual GDP over the next few years, there are undoubtedly very large opportunity costs in the form of sacrificed output and incomes that South Africans will be bearing.

It would be a loss equal to about 25% of GDP delivered in 2019. And may be compared with the extra R500b rand the government plans to spend or provided tax relief to assist an economic recovery. Though not all of this R500 billion spending or tax relief programme will represent extra spending by government that will have to funded one way or another. Some of it will be covered by re-allocating some of the previous budget. Is the government plan generous enough? Such a judgment would depend upon on the estimate of its economic costs and benefits -rather than a narrow view of its financial implications. It can be funded with extra money created for the purpose. It does not have to rely on issuing extra interest-bearing debt raised that would be a burden on future taxpayers.

The less reliant the government is on funding the spending with expensive debt, the better it will be for future taxpayers. The case for funding a temporary increase in government sending with a temporary increase in the money supply, as well as with the almost free money provided by the IMF and World Bank, is surely the right way to budget. There is nothing ever to stop a sovereign as for example SA with its own currency, issuing more money to pay for goods and services that none would refuse. Issuing non-interest bearing central bank money is not normally used as an alternative to taxes or genuine borrowing to fund government spending because if pushed to excess, beyond the willingness of those who receive money in  exchange to hold that money, it leads to inflation. Prices would tend to rise when the surplus money held by economic agents, including banks, is exchanged for goods and services and financial securities of all kinds including bank overdrafts. But in current crisis circumstances, when demand for goods and services is so depressed higher inflation, runaway inflation, is a distant threat. And one that can be removed by taking money out of circulation when the state of the economy is strong enough.

The sacrifices of income and output will not be shared equally by all South Africans. Many will lose jobs that will be difficult to replace. Others will lose their jobs and the businesses that self- employed them. Some businesses will survive better than others in the new world of business after Corona virus. Many will see the value of the pensions and retirement plans, their hard earned savings,  painfully reduced.

Businesses to survive will need a reserve of working capital to start up again. The banking system, with assistance from the government and its central bank, as is the intention,  can help those with viable businesses, but without the means to start them up again without additional bank credit. It would only be fair for the government that has so damaged the value of these enterprises, to help the banks do so- by creating money for the banks to deploy in the form of extra bank credit. And overspending to mitigate the damage caused would be better than underspending- especially if the charge to future taxpayers can be limited by money creation. At times like these traditional parsimony is not called for.

Would it be unfair to point out that those in SA who are employed by the government at all levels, will lose neither incomes nor the pension benefits the SA taxpayer has guaranteed them on retirement. Their willingness to accept a wage and salary freeze to help our fiscus when the economy returns to normal might seem a proper form of reciprocation.

The extra spending or tax relief offered by governments in response to the lock down, might add not only to demand for goods and services over the next two years, but can also encourage more output of goods and services. This stimulus to the supply side of the economy, as it is allowed to revive, will reduce the net loss of income and output. If this is the case such extra expenditure can in a real sense pay for itself. More demand that leads to more supply avoids any opportunity costs, the trade-offs that normally apply when resources are fully employed.

The actual GDP numbers over the next two years will be closely watched and used to update our GDP loss ratio in order to gauge the shape of the recovery. It will hopefully be a V shaped recovery as we have estimated – it could be a less helpful more prolonged  U shaped recovery, with an extended bottom to the U should the economy struggle to revive its spirits and confidence. The economic recovery might worse even take a double u (W) course. That is a brief recovery followed by a further decline and then only later a recovery.

The economic growth rates as they unfold will not mean what they usually do. And therefore should be treated with great care over the next few years. GDP growth rates are most often presented as annual percentage growth from quarter to quarter, when the GDP has been adjusted for seasonal influences and converted to an annual equivalent That is growth from one quarter in seasonally adjusted GDP to the next quarter is then raised to the power of 4 to provide an annualized growth rate. This is the growth rate that attracts headlines.

Two consecutive negative growth rates measured this way are regarded as indicating a ‘technical recession’. The implication of this annual equivalent growth rate is that quarterly growth is expected to continue at that pace for the next year. Clearly under the influence of lock downs growth, so measured, is likely to become even more variable than it usually is.

This will be especially true of Q2 2020 when the impact of the lock down will be at its most severe, perhaps  reducing  growth in GDP to a truly shocking negative rate of  minus 50% p.a or thereabouts.

Estimating growth on this quarter to quarter basis over the next few years will be a very poor guide to the underlying growth trends. Following our estimates of the loss ratio and GDP, as an example, would show a very sharp contraction in Q2 2020, to be followed by positive growth of 40% p.a. in Q3 and Q4, 10% in Q4 and then as much as 50% again in  Q2 2021. The recession will seemingly have been avoided and the economy will soon be recording boom time growth rates. This would present a highly misleading account of what has been going on with the economy.

If GDP is compared to the same quarter a year before we will get a much smoother series of growth rates. It is likely to  show negative growth throughout 2020, (down by as much as -20% p.a in Q2) with strongly positive growth of 30% resuming in Q2 2021 when measured off the highly depressed base of Q2 2020, when the lock down was at its most severe.

The better way to calculate the impact of the lock down in terms of growth rates would be to calculate the simple percentage change in GDP from quarter to quarter (not seasonally adjusted or annualized)  as the impact of the lock down unfolds and gradually, we should hope, dissipates. The worst quarters measured this way will be Q2 and Q3 2020 after which quarter to quarter growth in percentage terms will become positive. See the figure below that turns our estimates of quarterly GDP in current prices over the next few years into the alternative measures of growth rates.

 

 

Estimated Quarterly Growth rates between 2020 and 2022 under alternative conventions.

f1

Source; SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth and Investment

 

The upshot is that growth rates will not be able to tell what has happened to an economy when subject to a severe supply side shock – that is temporary in nature. Measuring in absolute terms, in money of the day GDP sacrificed each quarter, as we have attempted to estimate, will tell the full tale of economic destruction under way after the events.

Monetary and fiscal policy should be fully engaged avoiding such disappointments. Much lower short-term interest rates, combined with a degree of money creation by the Reserve Bank, to assist the banks and other lenders to take up the extra short dated and low yielding Bills to be issued by the Treasury, will be necessary to the purpose. A mixture of significantly more government spending, hopefully well directed, and  funded as cheaply as possible is called for to help revive the SA economy when it is given the opportunity to do so. Moreover there should be no sense of improper fiscal or monetary conduct acting this way.

It would be the right thing to do, and to do it openly without any sense of equivocation. As right a set of economic policy measures as they are being adopted in all the developed world whose economies are subject to similar proportionate losses of income and output. The developing world and South Africa does not deserve to be held to a different fiscal and monetary policy standard in circumstances like these. The time to resume sensible fiscal conservatism is when the economy is back to something like normal.

Covid-19 and the economy: Estimating the damage

We estimate what the extent of the damage of Covid-19 to the economy will be, and explain why the Reserve Bank and government should not hesitate to be bold in mitigating it.

How are governments and their central banks responding to the damage caused by the lockdowns forced upon their economies and their citizens? Are they doing all they can to minimise the damage to incomes sacrificed during the lock downs?

There is certainly no reluctance to spend. The issue is not about how much but rather how best to spend.  Restraints on fiscal deficits and money creation have been abandoned – rightly so in the circumstances.

When so much central bank lending is to the government, even via the secondary market that replaces other lenders, the distinction between monetary and fiscal policy falls away. The UK government made this clear when it exercised its right to a large overdraft on the Bank of England. The Bank could not and would not say no to such a demand for funding, given the state of the economy. The US Fed has added over US$2 trillion of cash to the US banking system over the week to 10 April. It increased its balance sheet by 50% over a very busy week. The federal government has budgeted for trillions of dollars of extra spending, including spending to cover possible losses on the Fed’s loan book.

Issuing money is usually the cheapest way for any government and its taxpayers to fund such emergency spending. When interest rates on long-term government debt are close to zero or even negative in parts of the developed world, issuing debt is almost as cheap as issuing money. Though the question should be asked: where would interest rates settle without the huge loans provided to governments and banks by their central banks?

This is not the case in SA and many other emerging economies. Issuing long-term debt at around 10% is an expensive exercise. Issuing three-month Treasury Bills at 5% is also expensive. For central banks to create money for their governments and taxpayers, would be a cheaper option. Is there not the same good reason for them to support government credit in the same exceptional circumstances as vigorously as is being done in the developed world to universal investor approval?

There is every reason for the SA government to rely heavily on its central bank at a time like this, with the same proviso as applies in the developed world. When the economy is again running at close to its potential, the stimulus should be withdrawn to avoid inflation. That test however will come later. There is an immediate challenge to be met now, and spending and lending without usual restraint is rising to the challenge.

How much economic output and income will be sacrificed over the period of the lockdown and the gradual recovery after that? A broad-brush comparison between what might have been without the coronavirus and what may yet happen to the SA economy can be made. The loss in output as a result of the shutdowns – the difference in what might have been produced and earned had GDP performed as normal in 2020 and 2021, and what now is likely to be produced, can be estimated, as we do below.

What might have been

We first estimate economic output and incomes (GDP at current prices measured quarterly), had the economy continued on its recent path, unaffected by the pandemic. To do this, we use the standard time series forecasting method. We extrapolate what might have transpired had GDP in money of the day continued to grow at its very pedestrian recent pace of about 4%-5% per annum. GDP inflation in recent years has been of the order of 4% per annum, indicating very little real growth was being realised. We then make a judgment about how much of this potential output will be lost due to the shutdowns. We estimate a GDP loss ratio for the quarters between Q1 2020 and Q4 2021 to calculate this difference between pre and post pandemic GDP.

The cumulative difference – the lost output and incomes over the next two years – we estimate as R1,071 trillion of lost output that will be sacrificed to contain the spread of the virus. This is equivalent to approximately 24% of what might have been the GDP in 2020

GDP and GDP after Covid-19 (quarterly data using current prices)

f1
Source: SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth & Investment
The loss ratio – the percentage of the economy that remains after the shutdown – is the crucial judgment to be made. We have assumed that the economy operated at 95% of its pre-pandemic potential in Q1 2020.  Then, as the impact of the lockdown intensifies through much of Q2, we estimate the economy will utilise only 75% of capacity in Q2. This, we assume, will be followed by somewhat less damage in Q3 when we assume the economy will operate at 80% of potential capacity as the lockdown is gradually relieved. We expect conditions to continue to improve by the equivalent of 5% each quarter, until the economy gets back to where it might have been without the lockdowns. We assume that to be in the second quarter of 2021.

This almost V-shaped recovery might well be too optimistic an estimate. The losses in 2020 may well be greater and the recovery slower than estimated. But the output gap – the difference between what could have been produced and what will be produced – will be a large one.

Loss of output ratio – GDP-adjusted/GDP estimate (pre-Covid-19)

f2
Source: SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth & Investment

Estimated loss in GDP per quarter in millions of rands (sum of losses 2020-2021 = R1,071 trillion)

f3
Source: SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth & Investment

Don’t hesitate to act boldly

The pace of recovery will depend in part on how much the government spends and how much the Reserve Bank supports the government and private sector with extra cash. The more support provided to the economy by the government and the Reserve Bank, the more demand will be exercised and the smaller will be the eventual loss of output. Any reduction in economic damage of the likely large order estimated is a clear gain to the economy.

Any additional utilisation of what would otherwise be wasted capacity comes without real economic cost. That extra demand can bring forth extra supplies that would be a pure gain to the economy, especially if funded with central bank money.

The Reserve Bank has the opportunity to create more of its own money, without any cost, to help borrowers. This includes not only the banks and the government, but also private businesses directly through its lending. Any inflation that may come along later with a recovery in the economy, can be dealt with in its own good time.

Unlike its peers in the developed world, it also has scope to significantly lower short-term interest rates, all the way to close to zero if needs be. It has rightly taken a step on the way with its emergency meeting recently and the welcome decision to cut rates by a further one percentage point (100bps). We would hope further cuts are on the way. A mixture of aggressive QE and lower interest rates are the right stuff for the SA economy.

Postscript on growth rates: they will not mean what they usually do after the crisis

GDP growth rates are most often presented as the annual percentage growth from quarter to quarter, adjusted for seasonal influences and converted to an annual equivalent. This is the growth rate that attracts headlines.

Two consecutive negative growth rates measured this way are regarded as indicating a ‘technical recession’. The implication is that  quarterly growth will continue at that pace for the next year. Under the a lockdown scenario, growth measured this way is likely to become much more variable than it usually is.

This will be especially true in Q2 2020, when the impact of the lockdown will be at its most severe, maybe reducing growth to an annual equivalent negative rate of growth of 50% or so. Estimating growth on this quarter-to-quarter basis over the next few years will however be a poor guide to the underlying growth trends. It may show a very sharp contraction in Q2 2020, followed by positive growth of 40% in Q3 and Q4, 10% in Q4 and then as much as 50% again in  Q2 2021. The recession will seemingly have been avoided and the economy will soon be recording boom time growth rates. A likely but highly misleading account of what will be going on with the economy, it must be said.

If GDP is compared to the same quarter a year before, we will get a much smoother series of growth rates. It is likely to show negative growth throughout 2020, (down by as much as -20% in Q2) with strong growth of 30% only resuming in Q2 2021, off a highly depressed base of Q2 2020 when the lockdown was at its most severe.

The better way to calculate the impact of the lockdown in terms of growth rates, would be to calculate the simple percentage change in GDP from quarter to quarter as the impact of the lockdown unfolds and gradually, we hope, dissipates. The worst quarters measured this way will be Q2 and Q3 2020, after which quarter-to-quarter growth in percentage terms will become positive.

Estimated quarterly growth rates between 2020 and 2022 under alternative conventions

f4
Source: SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth & Investment
The upshot of this is that growth rates will not be able to tell us what has happened to an economy subject to a severe supply side shock that is temporary in nature. Measured in absolute terms, in money of the day GDP sacrificed each quarter, as we have attempted to do, will tell the full tale of economic destruction.

The age of money creation; what will be the consequences of rapid growth in the money supply?

Dealing with a financial and economic crisis – by creating money

This is the age of money creation. Money creation à outranceto the limit – unsparingly[1] that began on a monumental scale in response to the Global Financial Crisis of 2008-9. (GFC) A new phase in money creation on an even greater scale has begun in response to the Corona Virus crisis. Or more precisely in response to the shutdowns of normal economic activity ordered by almost all governments. In the week ending April 10th the US Federal Reserve Banks, as an outstanding example, expanded its assets and liabilities sheet by an extraordinary 2 trillion dollars. It increased its assets and liabilities from approximately 4 to 6 trillion dollars or by 50% in one week. With more money likely to follow in the weeks ahead.

The recipe for curing a banking crisis has long been known- create more and enough money until the panic rush for money abates. It has been done this way many times before in response to one or other financial crisis. But it had never been practiced on the scale adopted after the GFC and now.

Analysing the balance sheets of central banks to find the sources of extra money

On the asset side of the Federal System you will find mostly securities issued by the US government. Its liabilities are mostly incurred in the form of deposits placed by member banks of the Federal Reserve System. The size of the Fed balance sheet has increased more than six times since 2008 – and it is set to rise much further.

These deposits with any central bank are money – central bank money – cash, if you like. Money that can be exchanged without limit for goods and services, other currencies and financial and tangible assets of all kinds. The cash so acquired by banks or others may also be used to make additional loans – bank overdrafts for example- or used to subscribe for new issues of securities offered by governments and businesses of all kinds, including other banks. They are money, because as with notes and coins of the realm, they would not be refused when offered in exchange for goods, services or other assets.

Whenever a central bank on its own initiative buys a security (a US Treasury Bill or Bond for example) or makes a loan to a bank or business, it settles the obligation to pay by crediting (digitally) its very own deposit accounts. In other words a central bank pays for whatever it wishes to buy, by creating its own money, at no extra cost to itself or the government of which the central bank is an agent. It may be described as a wholly owned subsidiary  of the government.

A few additional observations are in order. When the central bank buys an asset directly from a bank, that bank will in the first instance deposit the receipts of the sale in its account at the central bank. The money supply increases accordingly. When the asset is sold to the central bank by another financial institution, other than a bank, the proceeds will first be deposited in its account at some private bank. The bank receiving an extra deposit from a client will in turn present the digital equivalent of a cheque to the central bank for settlement and will receive a credit to its deposit account with the central bank. Again the money supply increases in proportion to the value of the transaction.

When however the central bank lends directly to the government in exchange for a newly issued security or against an increased overdraft, as the UK government is now doing, the government deposit account with the central bank will be credited accordingly. This larger government deposit account is not immediately part of the money supply. It is only when the government account is drawn upon to pay for goods and services, and the transactions are banked by suppliers to the government does the money supply increase in the form of extra deposits of private banks banked with the central bank.

Modern money is only convertible into the self-same money

Modern so-called fiat currencies are however not convertible at any fixed rate of exchange into gold or other reserve currencies. Yet they are easily converted into goods, services, assets of all kinds including gold and other currencies at variable exchange values that are continuously determined in the various markets. The purchasing power of its money is therefore not at all certain. It may lose buying power if there is too much of it issued – that is when more is supplied than is willingly held as money. Money may gain value in exchange for other currencies if extra demands to hold the money press upon existing supplies.

Money is held very willingly for its convenience as a transactions balance or as part of some optimal portfolio of assets. It is the most liquid, most easily exchanged of assets, with a certain monetary value. Other assets are less certain in their future value, expressed in money of the day. Though fiat money does have not a certain real or purchasing power value when exchanged for goods or other currencies.

Money as an asset is especially desirable when the prices of other assets are expected to fall in value. That is when the risks of business failure or the prospect of higher interest rates, that may reduce the value of income earning assets, appear more likely. But the owners of money may at any time decide that they have too much money in their portfolios and too little of other assets that they might use their surplus money or cash to acquire. That switch in the composition of any portfolio of assets may be more likely when the supply of money is seen to be increasing rapidly. Money holders may well they fear that their money will lose value over time and accordingly reduce their holdings of it. And by so doing put more upward pressure on the prices of goods, services and assets.

Central bank money is mostly demanded and supplied to banks. Will they hold the extra money or use it to make loans?

The principle owners of central money are the banks. And while they hold notes and coins to meet the demands of their customers in their tills and ATM’s, their major holdings of central bank money will be in the form of deposits with the central bank. Deposits of banks with the central bank may exceed the supply of notes and coin that make up the money issued by a central bank. (see figure below on the composition of the Federal Reserve Balance Sheet)

The decisions the banks take with their holdings of additional central bank money supplied to and received automatically by them will be crucial to the outcomes for total lending and spending in the economy. Essentially the more of the extra cash received the banks prefer to hold as extra cash reserves, the less will be the repercussions for the wider economy. An increase in the supply of money accompanied by an increase in the demand to hold that money cannot lead to extra bank lending. That is to additional supplies of bank credit that can be used to fund additional expenditure. The buck stops there – literally.

But banks are in business to make money – that is profits – by keeping as little cash on their books – as is prudent – and putting their cash to work by making loans. They earn profits on the spread between the interest they pay on deposit and the interest they earn on their loan portfolio- their assets. These deposits, especially those used to make payments are a convenient substitute for the notes and coins issued by the central bank into which they can be converted on demand. They are also described as part of the wider money supply.

The banks therefore not only borrow and lend, they maintain the payments system the reliability of which is crucial for economic stability. They incur costs including wages and rents costs attracting deposits or other sources of funds and transferring them on instruction of their deposit holders. They incur losses should their loans go sour. But without taking some risk with their cash and capital in search of profits they could not hope to succeed in the banking business.

They are in the risky business of lending and borrowing. They are typically highly leveraged businesses in two important senses. The amount of cash they hold in reserve against their deposit liabilities that may be withdrawn without notice is a minimal one – the legal requirement may be as low as a 2.5% reserve of cash against deposits. Banks will also hold equity capital as a reserve to cover losses on their loan book. This reserve ratio is also regulated to be as much as a 15% capital to asset ratio.

After the GFC most of the banks of the world behaved very untypically. They held onto much of the cash and did relatively little extra lending. They held cash reserves far in excess of the regulated reserve requirements as may be seen of the US banks in the figure below. The supply of cash was increasing at enormous rate after the GFC. But so was the demand to hold those reserves. Perhaps because the banks had become very risk averse in the aftermath of the GFC and held much larger cash reserves to feel safer. They did moreover receive interest on these deposits from the Fed. Competitive with the low money market rates available. No doubt this was further encouragement to hold on to cash

Bank credit grew relatively slowly in the US after the GFC and despite the surge in central bank money. as did the deposit liabilities of the US banks which are registered on the other side of their balance sheets. Thus the increase in the supply of central bank money, sometimes known as the money base (MB) or M0, did not lead to any dramatic increase in bank lending and spending associated with such extra lending. It was not inflationary as it turned out.

Recent money supply trends

In the figure below it should be noted how the money base (M0) in the US peaked in 2014 and then declined rapidly in 2018 – as QE was reversed. In late 2019 it rose sharply again to support the banking system that was found unexpectedly short of cash that put unwanted pressure on inter-bank lending rates. The most recent Corona virus-inspired surge in the money base can also be seen. The supply of currency by contrast has increased at a very steady rate- in response to the demands for dollar bills- in and outside of the US.

Fig. 1; Liabilities of the US Federal Reserve System.

f1

Source; Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis (Fred) Investec wealth and Investment

 

We show the asset side of the US Fed Balance sheet in the chart below. (figure 2)   As may be seen most of the growth in assets – and liabilities – was the result of the Fed purchase of US Treasury Bonds in the capital market. The other assets of the Fed include loans made to banks and mortgage backed securities issued by government agencies.

Fig.2; Total Assets of the Federal Reserve Bank System and Holdings of Treasury Bills and Bonds

f2

Source; Federal Reserve Bank of St.Louis. Investec Wealth and Investment

These Fed holdings of securities issued by the US Treasury have gained  an important share of all the debt incurred by the Federal Government – currently the Fed share is around 12% of all US government debt – as we show in figure 3 below.

Fig.3; Federal Debt and US Government Debt held by Federal Reserve System

f3

Source; Federal Reserve Bank of St.Louis. Investec Wealth and Investment

 

 

Increased Treasury Bond holdings of this magnitude have surely helped to reduce the interest rates paid on US Treasury Bonds. Since the Federal Reserve Bank of the US, while it keeps a separate set of accounts and balance sheet, is a wholly owned agency of the Federal Government. If we consolidated their balance sheets and set off the Reserve Bank’s holdings of Treasuries against the total Fed debt, we would reveal a reduction in outstanding Federal debt, replaced by the increased deposit liabilities of the Federal Reserve Banks. In other words cash – irredeemable non-interest bearing government debt – that is issued by the government or rather its central banks without interest – replacing interest bearing debt.  Though, when the interest paid on government debt, short and long dated, is very low- close to zero- as it is now in the US – the distinction between debt and money is largely irrelevant from the perspective of the issuer incurring the liability and not paying (much) interest

 

Explaining why bank deposits are a multiple of central bank money- but limited by it.

Central bank money, currency and cash reserves in the form of deposits with the central bank can be described more evocatively as “high powered money”. This is because the bulk of the money held and used to pay for goods and services is supplied by the private banking system in the form of transaction balances (deposits) held with them and exchanged on the instruction of depositors. The loans and advances banks make may flow from one bank to another. But the money loaned mostly stays with the banking system. They arrive as deposits with other banks or even as another  deposit of another customer of the bank making the loan. The funds lent, borrowed and spent do not drain away from the domestic banking system, except when withdrawn as notes or deposited in a foreign banking account.

It is the cash reserves held by banks  that sets the theoretical limit to the sum of the loans in one form or another that the banks may make. It therefore sets the limits to the so -called money multiplier – the multiple ratio of broadly defined money – known as M1 M2 or M3 made up of bank deposits of various kinds from transactions balances to longer term deposits- to  central bank money.

That ratio or multiplier as we show below was of the order of 14 times in SA M3/M0 or 8 times in the US M2/M0 before the GFC. It collapsed in the US to about 3 times as the demand of the banks to hold a much greater reserve of central bank money was exercised by the US banking system. It has increased recently to about four times the money base or M0. See figures 3 and 4 below.

South African banks by contrast with their US hold very little by way of excess cash reserves – cash reserves in excess of the regulated ratio- some 2.5% of deposit liabilities. Rather than holding excess reserves SA banks consistently borrow significant sums from the Reserve Bank to meet their demands for cash as we will demonstrate below. SA banks were not caught up short of cash in the GFC. They are now very much caught up in the crisis caused by the responses to the Corona virus. The loans they have made will not be easily serviced when their borrowers are not able to realise any revenue. Solvency and a lack of liquidity will threaten them as much in SA as it will do anywhere else.

 

Fig 4; South Africa Narrow and Broader definitions of the Money Supply and the money multiplier

f4

Source; SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth and Investment

Fig.5; US Money Supply and the money multiplier

f5

Source; Federal Reserve Bank of St.Louis. Investec Wealth and Investment

 

Private banks do not create money- they supply deposits that act as money at a cost – and not necessarily profitably

While these bank deposits can be measured as a multiple of the cash supplied to the system this does not mean that the banking system can “create deposits” in some magical, costless way. Supplying deposits to the system and maintaining the payments system to which a deposit account gives access, is a costly exercise. It takes computer systems and ATM machines and premises and people to manage the system and also equity capital that might be better employed in other businesses. And loans may not always be repaid. Banks may go broke if their bad loans exceed the value of their equity which may only be equivalent to 10-15 per cent of their loans and advances. And they may also go under if they cannot meet a run on the bank- a demand for cash in exchange for their deposits – which is their contractual obligation. Only the central bank can create money at will and without cost. The difference between private banks who supply deposits at a cost – and the central bank who can create money without cost is a fundamental one.

The limits to the size of a banking system- the aggregate value of its assets and liabilities -will be determined in any full analysis of the determinants of its size, by its profitability. Profitable banks grow their assets and their deposit liabilities – unprofitable banks shrink away. The profitability of a bank is enhanced by leverage – minimising as far as responsible its cash reserves and equity capital. Banks are typically highly leveraged businesses. But risk of failure in all enterprises comes with leverage and prudence may limit lending activity, and may have to mean larger cash and capital reserves, fewer loans and so reduced profitability and so a smaller money multiplier -as has been the case in the US since the GFC.

The habits of the customers of the banks, how much they prefer to use notes to make payments rather than accept bank deposits as payment, will also influence the cash reserve ratios of the banks and so the volume of their lending. The money habits of the community – a preference for money in the bank rather than in the pockets or purses or in offshore banks – may change only gradually over time- so limiting the growth over time in the banking system. The relative importance of a banking system might be measured as the ratio of bank assets and liabilities to GDP in money of the day prices. As may be seen in the figure below the real role of banking in the US and SA economies is not dissimilar- with M2 running at about 50 to 60 per cent of GDP. The SA ratio however increase markedly between 1980 and 2010. The US money to GDP ratio was stable even declining between 1990 and 2008, suggesting a relatively less important role for banks in the US economy, but has increased in since the GFC as may be seen in figure 6 below.

 

Fig.6; The Money (M2) to GDP ratios in SA and the US. Measuring the real importance of private banks.

f6

Source; Reserve Bank of SA, the Federal Reserve Bank of St.Louis and Investec Wealth and Investment.

 

An economy depends on a thriving profitable banking system – able to support growing businesses with convenient credit and a payments system.  Zombie banks – undercapitalised banks -that survive only on government and central bank life support – are not helpful for economic growth. They are poorly capitalised because they have not earned enough income to retain cash with which to augment their reserves of equity capital.

Furthermore it should be appreciated that every deposit made with a private bank represents a real saving – of consumption spending  – however temporary. Banks pool these savings to make them available to borrowers. Money in the bank is as much a saving- a reduction in potential spending out of income or wealth – as a contribution to a pension fund. It is a more liquid form of saving, they are savings more easily cashed in for goods, services or other assets at a certain money value.  Cash is an important component of any wealth portfolio and part of the working capital of any business.

However what is true of the deposits of a private bank that act as money in competition with the notes issued by the central bank – that they are costly to produce- is not true of the cash issued by a central bank. Such cash is almost costless to produce and can be supplied in unlimited quantities. It is convertible only into the same government sanctioned cash.

Why not fund government spending with cheap money? Responses to QE as  the exception not the monetary rule.

Why then should any government restrain the amount of money it creates that costs so little to produce? Why do governments fund their deficits from the market place rather than via their own central banks? The value of a currency that can be issued without limit is based on a trust that it will retain to a least some degree,  or at least temporarily retain its purchasing power, that is its value in exchange. Otherwise it is not very useful.

The limits to issuing money, is that issuing too much of it – more than would be willingly held as a reserve of purchasing power – is that the money created would consistently and even rapidly lose its value in exchange. That is it would cause inflation – defined as a continuous increase in the price level – and a persistent decline in the foreign exchange value of the currency and its purchasing power. This is usually not a politically popular outcome and so it is to be avoided. Hyper inflation is moreover highly destructive of the real economy.

Economies may adapt to moderate inflation- say inflation that runs between five and fifteen per cent per annum- especially if the rate of inflation though high becomes predictable. But inflation trends may easily slip higher should government come to rely more permanently and heavily on printing money rather than raising taxes or borrowing in a genuine way in the capital market. Inflation and currency depreciation would follow should the supply of central bank money consistently exceeded the demand of the public and the banks to hold that central bank money as a reserve.

QE after 2008—09 representing an extraordinary increase in the global supply of central bank money did not cause inflation because much of the extra cash issued was willingly held by the banks. Had the banks used the extra cash to make additional loans the supply of deposits (money broadly defined)  and the supply of bank credit would have grown proportionately – say at the eight times multiple normal before the GFC. And spending would have grown much faster than it did with the aid of much more bank credit and prices would have risen much faster than they did. Thus it is not the supply of money that automatically leads to more spending and higher prices. It is the excess supply of money- central bank money- over the demand to hold that money that causes bank credit to increase and prices to rise.

Time will tell what use is made of the extra cash created to fight Corona Virus. Will it be held mostly as additional cash reserves by the banks? Or will it stimulate a burst of extra bank lending and a multiple creation of deposits and a rapid expansion of bank credit and the extra spending associated with freely available bank credit? That is prove more inflationary than QE was last time round- post the GFC? The reactions to QE in SA – the scale of it and the trends in money supply and bank credit will be of particular interest.

The case of SA – how much QE will and should be undertaken?

There is no doubt that a large gap will open up in South Africa between the output and incomes that might have been produced without the lockdowns and what will be produced. The output gap will be a very large one. Perhaps the equivalent of 25% of one years GDP will be sacrificed to the cause of defeating the Corona virus. It will be a very large loss to bear. And much like the losses to be incurred in all the economies subject to lock down.

How much income will actually be sacrificed will depend in part on how much the SA government spends on relief measures and how much the Reserve Bank supports the government and private sector with extra cash. The more support provided to the economy in one way and another by the government and the Reserve Bank, the more demand for goods and services can be exercised and the smaller will be the eventual loss of output as supply responds as best it can. Any reduction in economic damage of the large likely order expected is a clear gain to the economy. Given the size of the output gap and a general lack of demand for goods and services, inflation in SA is very likely to remain subdued. This surely a time to be concerned about the lack of output and incomes, not that prices may be rising faster at some time in the future.

Any additional utilization of what would otherwise be wasted capacity- human and material- comes without real economic cost. That extra demand can bring forth extra supplies would be pure gain to the economy, especially if funded with central bank money. The Keynesian argument for extra spending by government, funded as cheaply as possible, holds very strongly when supply and demand in the economy can be confidently predicted to decline significantly- as it will in SA during the lock down.

It is not clear that the Reserve Bank sees the SA predicament in this same urgent way. In the way central banks in the developed world are recognizing the role they can play and acting accordingly. The SA Reserve Bank  has every  opportunity to create more of its own money without any cost. In order to help borrowers, and to assist the banks and the government,  but also to support hard pressed private businesses through its lending programmes. Unlike its peers in the developed world it also has scope to significantly lower short-term interest rates. All the way close to zero would make sense to help make up some of the output sacrificed with the lock down.

The Reserve Bank should not be hesitating to act boldly. Any inflation that may come along later with a recovery in the economy will have to be dealt with in its own good time. Money created can be as easily removed from circulation when the economy has closed its output gap. And a wider fiscal deficit can be temporary rather than permanent when economic normality is regained. The case for the SA government to limit its spending and fiscal deficits over the long run remains as strong as ever. But not for now. It calls for calm wisdom and good judgment. Unusual times call for unusual responses. Let us hope the SA Reserve Bank is up to the challenge.

[1] As described by Keynes. John Maynard Keynes was the originator of depression economics. He provided the justification for governments to spend more to overcome a lack of spending that caused the great depression in the nineteen thirties. And for which there appeared no self-correction. He inspired a highly  influential school of economics known as Keynesians. His argument for stimulation through government spending rather than monetary policy was that interest rates could not fall far enough to encourage enough capital expenditure. But he never, as far as I am aware, advocated printing money to fund extra government spending. While logical enough to use money to fund government spending if the depression was a deep one, he knew such a proposal would be politically unacceptable. For fear of inflation of the Weimar republic that was not far from memories in the nineteen thirties when Keynes developed his ideas..

Has the US market crash fully discounted the permanent loss of earnings?

Does the reduced value of the S&P 500 reflect the earnings permanently lost after the coronavirus? We give a provisional answer.

The tribe of company analysts is hard at work revising the target prices (almost all lower) of the companies they follow. They will be adjusting the numerators of their present value calculations for the permanent losses of operating profits or free cash flow caused by the lockdowns. They will attempt to estimate the more long-lasting impact on the future performance of the companies they cover, after they get back to something like pre-coronavirus opportunities.
What discount rate will they apply to the expected post-coronavirus flow of benefits to shareholders? Will it be higher for the pandemic risk or lower because long bond yields are expected to remain low for the foreseeable future? When they have revised their target prices for the companies they cover, we could theoretically add up how much less all the companies covered by the analysts are now estimated to be worth. We would count the total damage to shareholders in trillions of US dollars since 1 January.

The analysts are taking much longer than usual to revise their estimates of forward earnings and target prices. But investors in shares are an impatient lot. They are making up their own collective minds, also with difficulty, as the turbulent markets and the high cost of insuring against market moves shows.

The companies listed in the S&P 500 Index were worth a collective US$28.1 trillion on 1 January 2020. By 23 February, when the market peaked, they had a still higher combined market value of US$29.4 trillion. By 23 March, the market had deducted nearly US$10 trillion off the value of these listed companies. Yet by 17 April, the market had recovered strongly from its recent lows, and was worth US$24.6 trillion, or US$3.5 trillion less than the companies were worth on 1 January. Is this too low or too high an estimate of permanent losses?

Figure 1: The market value of companies listed in the S&P 500, to 23 April 23 2020

f1

Source: Bloomberg and Investec Wealth & Investment

We will try to answer these questions. First, we attempt to estimate the damage to S&P reported earnings. These lost earnings can be compared with the losses registered in the market place, the US$3.5 trillion of value destruction. To do so, we first extrapolate S&P earnings beyond 2019, using a time series forecasting method. This forecast is used to establish the S&P earnings that might have been, had the economy not been so cruelly interrupted. We then estimate the earnings that are now likely to be reported, by assuming a loss ratio. That is the ratio between the earnings that we predict will be reported as a ratio to the earnings that might have been, had the US not been disrupted by the coronavirus.

As we show in the figure below, the reduction in reported earnings is assumed to be very severe in Q2 2020, when earnings to be reported in Q2 are assumed to be equivalent of only 25% of what might have been had the earnings path continued at pre-crisis levels. Then the loss ratio is assumed to decline to 30% in Q3, 50% in Q4 2020, and 75% in Q1 2021, where after it is estimated to improve by 5% a quarter until the earnings path is regained in Q2 2022.

The calculations are indicated in the charts below. The total accumulated loss in earnings under these assumptions would be a large US$3.4 trillion. It will be seen that the growth in estimated S&P 500 earnings turns positive, off a very low base, as early as Q2 2021. The key assumption for this calculation is the loss ratio, as well as the time assumed to take until back to the previous path. The more elongated the shape of recovery and the greater the loss ratios, the more earnings will be sacrificed.

If this assumed permanent loss of over US$3.4 trillion were subtracted from the pre-coronavirus crisis value of the S&P 500 of US$28 trillion, it would bring the S&P roughly to the value of about US$24 trillion recorded on 17 April.

Figure 2: The quarterly flow of S&P earnings in billions of US dollars

f2
Source: Bloomberg and Investec Wealth & Investment

Figure 3: Estimated quarterly loss of earnings per quarter (billions of US dollar) and growth in estimated earnings (year-on-year) 2019-2022

f3
Source: Bloomberg and Investec Wealth & Investment
How much S&P 500 gross earnings will be lost permanently is still to be determined with any degree of confidence. The US$3.4 trillion loss we estimate is consistent with the losses recorded to date in the market value of the S&P 500 companies. The environment after the coronavirus and the impact of the new political economy will have to be considered carefully when assessing the long-term prospects for businesses. As always, the discount rate applied to future economic profits will have a decisive role to play in determining the present values of companies.

Monetary policy in South Africa – Carpe Diem

Published in Business Day 17. April 2020.

 

The SA government will double its fiscal deficit in response to the Coronavirus crisis and its impact on output and incomes. The losses in output and incomes from the lock downs may be of the order of one trillion rand of sacrificed output and incomes. They will certainly be large, perhaps as much as one trillion rand of lost output, or the equivalent of 25% of GDP in 2019. We can only hope the extra government spending is highly effective and well directed to minimize the damage caused. It will help close the output gap, the difference between much lower realized GDP, and what might have been GDP, without the lock downs.  Encouraging more demand for goods and service will helpfully also increase the supply of them and increase incomes accordingly.

 

A spirit of generosity rather than any niggardliness is the right way for the government to approach its responsibilities for the economic damage it has inflicted. It should however be made very clear that whatever relief it offers and how offered is temporary in its nature. It is an urgent response to a grave emergency. Policies for the long term remain to be determined in the usual considered way, subject to all the usual due process.  We are hostage to a crisis – not to the future.

 

The government should therefore hope to raise the emergency funds it intends to spend as cheaply as possible. This means borrowing at the short end of the bond market at very low rates of interest- as close to zero as we can get them. And we can get these short-term interest rates as low as we choose to set them. The shortest and cheapest way to fund the surge in spending would be to create money to the purpose. This is what every central bank in the developed world is doing enthusiastically and without shame. We should be doing the same as unapologetically.

 

The developed world faces much lower long-term interest rates than we do. They can issue long term date without paying much interest at all. And their borrowing costs are as low as they are because of the willingness of their central banks to buy vast amounts of government bonds in the market. This process now known as Quantitative Easing (QE) is money creation by another name. Their central banks are doing vastly more bond buying and additional lending to banks and businesses in response to the economic threat posed by Coronavirus. And they are creating much more money and holding down the interest their governments must pay for funds.

 

Addditional central bank money comes mostly in the form of bank deposits held with a central bank. The supply of money in SA increases every time the Reserve Bank makes a loan to a bank or buys foreign exchange or government securities in the market. Money in the form of additional bank deposits(cash) held with the Reserve Bank would also increase should the Treasury draw on its own considerable deposits with the Reserve Bank to make payments. It has over R160b in its deposit account with the Resbank and presumably does not need Reserve Bank permission to draw upon. If so it can do its own money creation.

 

The high cost of the RSA borrowing on a long term basis – 10% p.a. to borrow rands for ten years – is even more reason for us now to rely on the central bank to assist in a sensible funding plan for Corona virus relief. It means bringing down short rates further and sharply. And making enough extra cash available to the banks and other eligible borrowers on favourable terms, so that the banks can fully support the market in issues of short dated, low interest paying, Treasury Bills and Bonds. Supporting issues of short term debt that will and should be growing rapidly to fund the extra spending. We should fully eschew long term borrowing for now and replace maturing long term debt with short.

 

All the world including SA will be set for a post-Coronavirus battle over the future scope of government spending. On how much the government should intervene. The left will want more intervention – more spending – more regulation  – more taxation of the wealthy – and will fudge the dangers of relying on central banks to cover larger fiscal deficits. Monetising government is very likely to be inflationary if done permanently on a large scale. But it will not be inflationary in SA for now- not until after the crisis. When we can get back to a new normal- that will include sensible monetary and fiscal policy.

 

Time for the Reserve Bank to seize the moment

How are governments and their central banks responding to the damage from the lock downs forced upon their economies and their citizens? They are doing all they can to minimize the damage to incomes sacrificed during the lock downs. There is no reluctance to spend- the issue is not about how much but rather how best to spend.  Restraints on fiscal deficits and money creation have been abandoned – and rightly so in the circumstances.

When so much central bank lending is to the government, even via the secondary market replacing other lenders, the distinction between monetary and fiscal policy falls away. The British government made this clear when it exercised its right to a large overdraft on the Bank of England. The Bank could not and would not say no to such a demand for funding, giving the state of the Kingdom. The US Fed has added over 2 trillion dollars of cash to the US banking system over the week to April 10th. That is increased its balance sheet by 50% over a very busy week. The federal government has budgeted for trillions of dollars of extra spending- including spending to cover possible losses on the Fed’s loan book.

Issuing money is usually the cheapest way for any government and its taxpayers to fund such emergency spending. Though when interest rates on long term government debt is close to zero – more so if interest rates are negative – as in the developed world- issuing debt is almost as cheap as issuing money. Though where would interest rates settle without the huge loans provided to governments and banks by their central banks?

This is not the case in South Africa and many other emerging economies. Issuing long term debt at around 10% p.a. is an expensive exercise. Issuing three-month Treasury Bills at 5% p.a is also expensive. For central banks to create money for their governments and tax-payers is a much cheaper option. Is there not the same good reason for them to support government credit in the same exceptional circumstances as vigorously as  is being done in the developed world to universal investor approval?

There is every reason for the SA government to rely heavily on its central bank at a time like this. With the same proviso as applies in the developed world. That is when the economy is again running close to its potential the stimulus should be withdrawn to avoid inflation. That test however will come later. There is an immediate challenge to be met now. And spending and lending without usual restraint is rising to the challenge.

How much economic output and income will be sacrificed over the period of the lock-down and the gradual recovery after that? A broad- brush comparison between what might have been without Corona and what may yet happen to the SA economy can be made. The loss in output as a result of the shut downs – the difference in what might have been produced and earned had GDP performed as normal in 2020 and 2021, and what now – post Corona- is likely to be produced has been estimated as follows.

We first estimate economic output and incomes (GDP at current prices measured quarterly)  had the economy continued on its recent path unaffected by Corona. To do this we use standard time series forecasting method. That is to extrapolate what might have transpired had GDP in money of the day continued to grow at its very pedestrian recent pace of about 4- 5 per cent per annum. GDP inflation in recent years has been of the order of four per cent per annum meaning indicating very little real growth was being realized as is well known. We then make a judgment about how much of this potential output will be lost due to the shutdowns. We estimate a GDP loss ratio for the quarters between Q1 2020 and Q4 2021 to calculate this difference between pre and post Corona GDP.

The cumulative difference – the lost output and incomes over the next two years we estimate as of the order of R1,071,486 millions – that is approximately R1 trillion of lost output will be sacrificed to contain the spread of the virus. This one trillion is equivalent to approximately 24% of what might have been the GDP in 2020. (See figures below)

 

GDP and GDP after Corona (Quarterly Data Current Prices)

p1

 

Source; SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth and Investment

The loss ratio – the percentage of the economy that remains after the shutdown is the crucial judgment to be made. We have assumed that the economy operated at 95% of its pre-Corona potential in Q1 2020.  Then as the impact of the lock down intensifies through much of Q2, the economy it is estimated will utilize only 75% of capacity in Q2. This, it is assumed, will be followed by somewhat less damage in Q3 when the economy is assumed to be operating at 80% of potential capacity as the lockdown is gradually relieved. Conditions are then expected to continue to improve by the equivalent of 5% each quarter. That is until the economy gets back to where it might have been without the lock downs assumed to be in the second quarter of 2021.

This almost V shaped recovery might well be too optimistic an estimate. The losses in 2020 may well be greater and the recovery slower than estimated. But the output gap – the difference between what could have been produced and what will be produced, for want of demand as well as ability to supply, will be a very large one.

Loss of Output Ratio – GDP Adjusted/GDP Estimate (pre-Corona)

p2

Source; SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth and Investment

 

Estimated Loss in GDP per Quarter (R millions) Sum of losses 2020-2021 = R107146m

p3

Source; SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth and Investment

 

The pace of recovery will depend in part on how much the government spends and how much the Reserve Bank supports the government and private sector with extra cash. The more support provided to the economy in one way and another by the government and the Reserve Bank, the more demand will be exercised and the smaller will be the eventual loss of output. Any reduction in economic damage of the large likely order estimated is a clear gain to the economy. Any additional utilization of what would otherwise be wasted capacity- human and material- comes without real economic cost. That extra demand can bring forth extra supplies would be pure gain to the economy, especially if funded with central bank money.

It is not clear that the Reserve Bank sees the SA predicament in this same urgent way. In the way central banks in the developed world are seeing and acting. It has the opportunity to create more of its own money without any cost – to help borrowers –not only the banks and the government but also private businesses directly through its lending. Unlike its peers in the developed world it also has scope to significantly lower short-term interest rates. All the way close to zero would make sense. It should not be hesitating to act boldly. Any inflation that may come along later with a recovery in the economy will have to be dealt with in its own good time.

Post-Script on Growth Rates They will not mean what they usually do post the crisis.

GDP growth rates are most often presented as annual percentage growth from quarter to quarter when the GDP has been adjusted for seasonal influences and converted to an annual equivalent That is growth from one quarter in seasonally adjusted GDP to the next quarter raised to the power of 4. This is the growth rate that attracts headlines.  (Q1 is always a below average GDP quarter)

Two consecutive negative growth rates measured this way are regarded as indicating a ‘technical recession’. The implication of this measure is that  quarterly growth will continue at that pace for the next year. Clearly under the influence of lock downs growth measured this way is likely to become much more variable than it usually is.

This will be especially true in Q2 2020 when the impact of the lock down will be at its most severe- maybe reducing annual growth to an annual equivalent negative rate of growth of 50% or so. Estimating growth on this quarter to quarter basis over the next few years will be a very poor guide to the underlying growth trends. It may show a very sharp contraction in Q2 2020  to be followed by positive growth of 40% p.a. in Q3 and Q4, 10% in Q4 and then as much as 50% again in  Q2 2021. The recession will seemingly have been avoided and the economy will soon be recording boom time growth rates. A likely and highly misleading account of what will be going on with the economy it must be agreed.

If GDP is compared to the same quarter a year before we will get a much smoother series of growth rates. It is likely to  show negative growth throughout 2020, (down by as much as -20% p.a in Q2) with strongly positive growth of 30% only resuming in Q2 2021, off a highly depressed base of Q2 2020 when the lock down was at its most severe.

The better way to calculate the impact of the lock down in terms of growth rates would be to calculate the simple percentage change in GDP from quarter to quarter as the impact of the lock down unfolds and gradually, we hope, dissipates. The worst quarters measured this way will be Q2 and Q3 2020 after which quarter to quarter growth in percentage terms will become positive.

Estimated Quarterly Growth rates between 2020 and 2022 under alternative conventions.

p4

Source; SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth and Investment

The upshot of this is that growth rates will not be able to tell what has happened to an economy subject to a severe supply side shock – that is temporary in nature. Measuring in absolute terms , in money of the day GDP sacrificed each quarter, as we have attempted to do will tell the full tale of economic destruction.

GDP Normal GDP Adjusted for Corona. R million Aggregate Losses R835b  GDP at Current Prices= 5888b in 2019 -Approximately 14% of one year’s GDP

p5

 

Quantitative Easing and the money supply process- will it lead to inflation this time round?

Central Banks around the world are launching a new phase of accelerated money creation now known as Quantitative Easing or QE.  They are doing so in response to the economic contraction caused by the Corona Virus and the lock downs of economic activity intended to limit the spread of the virus. The scale of this QE and its consequences for economic activity asset prices and inflation are still to be revealed.

 

Click to read the full paper here.

What a difference a week makes – to all of us and the Reserve Bank

An extraordinary week has passed. When the government ordered and prepared for a shut-down of much (how much??) economic activity to deal with the health crisis. All, including the participants in capital markets, have tried to come to terms with the evolving realities at home and abroad. And it was a week when the SA Reserve Bank moved from conventional to unconventional monetary policy.

The Bank at its monetary policy proceedings on the 17th March reported in an explicitly conventional way. It cut its key repo rate by an unusually large 100bp- on an improved inflation outlook. By the 25th March it was practicing Quantitative Easing (QE) buying RSA bonds in the market to reduce “…excessive volatility in the prices of government bonds…”  and freely  providing loans to the banks of up to 12 months.

The Bank is therefore creating money of its own volition. Cash reserves, that is deposits of the private banks with the Reserve Bank, are created automatically when the Reserve Bank buys government bonds and shorter-term from the banks or its customers. These deposits serve as money – and are created without any cost to the issuer- the central bank- acting as the agent of the government. These additional cash reserves support the balance sheets of the banks. And could lead to extra lending by them, as is the intention

Had the Reserve Bank not acted as it did, the bond market would surely have remained volatile. But more importantly it might not have been able to absorb a deluge of bonds and bills that the government would be issuing to fund its emergency spending. Including coping with a draw-down of R30b of bonds sold by the Unemployment Insurance Fund to generate cash for the government to spend on income relief.

The yield on the 10 year RSA was about 9% p.a. in early March. By March 24th it was over 12% p.a. and declined marginally in response to the Reserve Bank intervention. The derating of SA credit by Moody’s on the Friday evening, after the market had closed, seemed inevitable in the circumstances. On the Monday morning the yields on long dated RSA bonds jumped higher on the opening of the market and then receded and ended as they were at the close on Friday (see figures below)

 

RSA Five and Ten-Year Bond Yields Daily Data 2020 to March 27th

p2

Source; Bloomberg and Investec Wealth and Investment

 

 

 

RSA 10 year Bond yield 26 -30 March Intra day movements

 p2

 

 

Central banks all over the world are also doing money creation – in very great quantities. Doing so as a predictable response to their own lock downs and collapse of economic activity and its threats to financial stability. But in the developed world they deal for bonds and other securities at much lower interest rates. Though no doubt the scale of their bond and other asset buying programmes (QE) is part of the explanation for very low yields – both short and long. Yet despite money creation on a vast scale more inflation is not expected in the developed world.

Not so in SA as we have indicated and in many other emerging markets. Issuing longer dated government bonds in their own currencies is a very expensive exercise. And has become more expensive post Corona.

Lenders to emerging market governments, in their own currencies, demand compensation for high rates of inflation expected, and receive compensation for the inflation risks There is always the chance that the purchasing power of interest income contracted for, and the real value of the debt when repaid, will be eroded by inflation of the local currency.

The danger is that fiscally strained governments will, sometime in the future, yield to the temptation to inflate their way out of the constraints imposed by bond investors.  By turning to their central banks, to fund their spending to a lesser or greater degree, rather than to an ever more demanding bond market.  Issuing money (creating deposits) at the central bank to finance spending carries no interest cost. It can be highly inflationary depending on how much money is created and how quickly the banks use the extra cash to extend loans to their customers.

The growing risk that SA would get itself into a debt trap and create money to get out of it has been the major force driving long-term RSA yields on RSA debt higher in recent years. Higher both absolutely and relative to interest rates in the developed world. Bond yields have risen for fear that SA would create money for the government to spend in response to ever growing budget deficits and borrowing requirements and a fast-growing interest bill. As the SA government has now done with the co-operation of the Reserve Bank- though in truly exceptional circumstances and justifiably so.

Avoiding the debt trap, controlling budget deficits and convincing investors and credit rating agencies that the country can fund its spending over the long term without resort to money creation, is the task of fiscal policy. For SA to regain a reputation for fiscal conservatism and an investment grade credit rating is now more unlikely than it was when a promising realistic Budget was presented in February.

The Reserve Bank may hope to control domestic spending and so inflation through its interest rate settings.  It does not however control inflation expected and so the interest rates established in the bond market. The more inflation expected the higher will be interest rates. Expected inflation over the long run is dependent in part on the expected fiscal trends and the likelihood of a resort to money creation. And these fiscal trends, thanks to Corona virus, have deteriorated as they have almost everywhere else.

How therefore should the government and the Reserve Bank react to current conditions in the bond market? Long term yields are unlikely to recede significantly; and the yield curve is likely to get steeper should the Reserve Bank reduce its repo rate further – as it is likely to do.

The government should therefore fund as much as it can at the cheapest, very short end of the capital market. To issue more short dated Treasury Bills to fund current spending and to replace long dated Bonds as they mature with shorter term obligations.  It will save much interest this way. The actions of the Reserve Bank by adding liquidity (cash) to the money market through QE will have made it much easier to borrow short from the banks and others.

And when the economic crisis is behind us it will remain essential to strictly control government spending to regain access to the long end of the bond market on more favourable terms.  Only the consistent practice of fiscal discipline will deserve and receive lower longer-term borrowing costs.

The Corona virus is much more than a health crisis

Nobody knows with any degree of confidence how long the economic disruption caused by the responses to the Corona virus will last. And just how much output and income and wealth (savings) will have been sacrificed.

The survival of any business that services crowds of people is gravely threatened as the Chinese lock-down approach to limit infections is widely adopted.  Collateral damage to those enterprises and the large number of self-employed who depend upon opportunities to earn income generated by airlines and airports, cruise ships, hotels, shops, restaurants, theatres, conference, sporting events and their like, even retailers, will be considerable. Including damage to the banks and others who provide them with credit. The margin of safety for many businesses and the self-employed is always very narrow. They will need financial reserves as well as assistance from governments to survive the turmoil.

Perhaps as much of 10% of one year’s global incomes and output will be sacrificed to contain the virus. This is an enormous sacrifice that is being made to overcome a virus that we are informed is not that morbid and comes with limited mortality risk. Currently 180,000 people around the world have been infected. Many have now recovered. The number of victims will surely rise – perhaps treble – before the tide turns if the Chinese evidence is relevant.

What we will never know with any certainty is how many infections and deaths will have been avoided as a result of the shutdowns. Some heartless economist will no doubt attempt to calculate the cost in GDP sacrificed for each death avoided- as well as the present value of the lives saved in the form of future earnings -the narrow economic benefit of saving – mostly old lives. It will be a very large number.

It is obvious that any such cost-benefit analysis has not informed policy in any way. Admirably only potential benefits, numbers of lives saved, have driven the responses made. And taking the pressure off health systems that would otherwise have been overwhelmed by the number of supplicants has been the means to the end of saving more lives. Perhaps when the dust is settled the issue of how to develop a health system capable of responding to an emergency of this kind will be addressed – as a more effective solution than putting people off work.

It is a however a generous response that only a relatively well-endowed society with a large reserve of spending power could possibly make. Without such a reserve to provide relief to those unable to earn any income would suffer terribly for want of life’s essentials. And using the reserve to keep businesses and banks afloat so that they can fight another day also makes good economic sense.

The government spending and financial taps are therefore being opened wide- wider than ever. Central banks are not only creating money to buy government bonds they are also buying shares in businesses and securities issued by them. And are offering loans on generous terms not only to banks but directly to businesses. Taxes are being relieved and postponed and access to unemployment benefits widened. Aid to businesses, for example airlines, will be provided on a large scale. The extra spending so facilitated will reduce the loss of output. It will help pay for itself.

South Africa and too many South Africans have little by way of reserves against economic disasters. Our fiscal space is highly constrained as our Budget proposals have made clear. And raising debt to fund extra spending has become even more expensive for SA after the crisis. Yet monetary policy in SA has lots of room to help our economy. There is room for the Reserve Bank to cut interest rates significantly and to offer financial support for banks and businesses. Our frail economy will need all the help it can get. Let us hope that the Reserve Bank can think – must think and act- beyond the narrow inflation fighting box it has hitherto confined itself.

Appraising the Budget- will the economic future be much better than the past?

The 2020 Budget tax and expenditure proposals are steps in the right direction for the SA economy. Holding the line on real government spending and avoiding a growth defeating increase in tax rates, is part of the right mix of policies.

The SA economy is hostage to fortune as well as to its economic policy proposals. Market reaction to the Corona virus overtook the Budget proposals that were initially well received in the market place.  RSA 10 year bond yields were 8.76% p.a the day before the Budget on the 26th February and 60bp lower immediately on the Budget news. They were up to 9.1% on the 2nd March. They then declined to 8.76% on March 4th after the Fed in a Corona pre-empt, cut its benchmark rate by 50bp and US 10y Treasury Bond yields went below 1%

RSA bonds are not a safe-haven asset for investors inside and outside the country as are US Treasuries and the dollar itself.  Yet were SA to be convincingly judged to be avoiding the debt trap and its money creation and inflationary dangers, taxpayers will gradually be rewarded with lower interest rates and interest expenses on their RSA debts. Global events that are now adversely affecting all EM borrowers and their currencies notwithstanding

The continued failures of the SA economy are elaborated upon in full grim even pious detail in the Budget Review.  Some Treasury mea-culpa would however be entirely appropriate for what has gone so badly wrong on the Treasury watch. Most egregious was the failure to recognize and contain operating costs at Eskom. And earlier to have permitted the explosion of public sector employment benefits in the boom years after 2005. We could have done with a Sovereign Wealth Fund then, reinforced by successful BEE partnerships with it.

The Budget Review contains a broad reform agenda. Including most helpfully bringing the employment benefits of government employees back in line with  “ .. the rest of the economy….” and promises legislation to “…eliminate excessive salaries and bonuses being awarded to executives and managers…” in the public sector that are indefensible. Eliminating the state’s “… complex and often ineffective procurement system. ….” is a reform long overdue.  And the intended reform of the exchange control system to best OECD practice is especially welcome for the wealth friendly signals it emits. Undertaking the “…urgent regulatory reforms of the Ports …”  would be a good step. But not only corporatizing the ports and cutting them loose from Transnet but allowing  them to compete with each other for custom would be much better for the economy.

Staying well out, as intended, of the “….exports of intellectual property..” will greatly encourage the creation of IP. To  “ Reduce the corporate tax rate”  in line with the competition and eliminating many of the complex tax allowances is essential. It is these complications that are responsible for “…South Africa’s tax incentive system…”  that “…favours incumbents and those able to afford specialist tax advice…”

Eliminating the extraordinarily large R600b liability for Third Party accidents of the Road Accident Fund (RAF) as was alluded to in the Budget Speech, would improve the State balance sheet. R2 per liter paid at the pump for the RAF could then be saved by households and businesses. Private insurance companies are more than capable of offering compulsory third-party cover at competitively determined rates. And capable of effectively contesting damage claims in court.

A debt for equity swap with Eskom debt holders is essential to the purpose of making it financially viable- otherwise a further R112b will  be coming its way, on top of the R62b provided to date. And with no guarantees that operating results will improve.

Debt swaps on agreed terms that introduced influential private shareholders to help govern the company will make Eskom economically viable. It would reward its managers conditional on improvements in return on capital. And pay them well enough – which is the usual private sector method for adding economic value.

Wallowing in despair at the highly unsatisfactory economic condition of SA is not helpful. Past failures can be seen as providing much scope for improvement. Hopefully the Budget proposals can provide an upside surprise for the SA economy.

Are the global markets right- about permanently low returns?

 

If we are to take seriously the signals from global bond markets- as we should- savers should expect a decade or more of very low returns. The decline in bond yields due to mature in 10 years or more accelerated dramatically during and after the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) (see below)

p1

 

 

 

 

Less inflation expected is part of the explanation for these lower yields. But it is more than lower expected inflation at work. Yields on inflation protected securities – those that add realized inflation to a semi-annual payment – have declined to rates below zero. Before the GFC the US offered savers up to a risk free 3% p.a. return for 10 years, after inflation. The equivalent real yield today is a negative one of (-0.11% p.a). (see below)

 

Real Yields in the US 10 year Inflation Linked Bonds ( TIPS)

p2

Source; Bloomberg and Investec Wealth and Investment

These low risk-free rates also mean that firms investing the capital of their shareholders have very low investment hurdles to clear to justify their investment decisions. A 6% internal rate of return would be enough to satisfy the average shareholder given the competition from fixed interest. Equity returns might also be expected to gravitate to these lower levels.

Another way to describe these capital market realities is that the rate at which the value of pension and retirement plans can be expected to compound is expected to be at a much slower one than they have  been in the recent past. Savers will need to save significantly more of their incomes to realise the same post-retirement benefits.

The past decade has in fact been particularly good for global pension funds.  In the ten years after 2010 the global equity index  returned 10.5% p.a. on average while a 60-40 blend of global equities and global bonds returned an average 6.4% p.a. with less risk. US equities would have served investors even better, realizing average returns of 13.4% p.a,  well ahead of US inflation of 1.8% p.a. over the period.

Total portfolio returns 2010-2019 (January 2010 =100)

p3

Source; Bloomberg and Investec Wealth and Investment

 

Why then has global capital become so abundant and cheap over recent years? Many would think that Quantitative Easing  (QE) the creation of money on a vast scale by the global central bankers, has driven up asset prices and depressed expected returns. An additional three and more trillion US dollars-worth has been added to the stock of cash since the GFC.

Global Money Creation

p4

Source; Bloomberg and Investec Wealth and Investment

 

But almost all of this cash has been added to the cash reserves of banks- and not exchanged for financial securities or used to supply credit to businesses that could have stimulated extra spending. Bank credit growth has remained muted in the US and even more muted in Europe and Japan.

The supply of global savings has in fact held up rather better than the demand for them, helped by an extraordinary increase in the gross savings to GDP ratio in Germany. These savings have increased from about 22% of GDP in 2000 to 30% of GDP in 2018- while the investment ratio has remained at around 22% of GDP. Government budget surpluses have contributed to this surplus of savings in Germany. For advanced economies the share of government expenditure in GDP has fallen from 42% in 2010 to 38% in 2018 while the share of revenue has remained stable at about a lower 35% of GDP. This could be described as global fiscal austerity  -post the confidence sapping GFC.

Germany – Gross Savings and Investment to GDP ratios

p5

Source; IMF World Economic Outlook Data Base and Investec Wealth and Investment

IMF – All Advanced Economies – Ratio of Government Expenditure and Revenue to GDP

p6

Source; IMF World Economic Outlook Data Base and Investec Wealth and Investment

Perhaps depressing the demand for capital may be the changing nature of business investment. Production of goods and more so of the services that command a growing share of GDP, may well have become capital light.  Investment in R&D may not be counted as capital at all. Nor is intangible capital as easily leveraged.

Lower interest rates have their causes -they also have their effects. They are very likely to encourage more spending – by governments and firms and households. Mr.Trump does not practice fiscal austerity. Boris Johnson also appears eager to spend and borrow more. It would be surprising if firms and many more governments did not respond to the incentive to borrow and spend more and compete more actively for capital. Permanently low interest rates and returns and low inflation may be expected – but they are not inevitable. The cure for low interest rates (high asset prices) might well be low interest rates.